Quantum finance

{{short description|Subfield of econophysics which applies quantum theory to finance}}

{{Use dmy dates|date=December 2021}}

Quantum finance is an interdisciplinary research field, applying theories and methods developed by quantum physicists and economists in order to solve problems in finance. It is a branch of econophysics.

Quantum continuous model

{{Primary sources section|talk=Quantum continuous model|date=January 2025}}

Most quantum option pricing research typically focuses on the quantization of the classical Black–Scholes–Merton equation from the perspective of continuous equations like the Schrödinger equation. Emmanuel Haven builds on the work of Zeqian Chen and others,{{cite journal|author=Zeqian Chen |title=Quantum Theory for the Binomial Model in Finance Theory|journal=Journal of Systems Science and Complexity|year= 2004 |arxiv=quant-ph/0112156|bibcode = 2001quant.ph.12156C }} but considers the market from the perspective of the Schrödinger equation.{{cite journal |author=Haven, Emmanuel |title=A discussion on embedding the Black–Scholes option pricing model in a quantum physics setting |year= 2002 |doi=10.1016/S0378-4371(01)00568-4|bibcode = 2002PhyA..304..507H |volume=304 |issue=3–4 |journal=Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and Its Applications |pages=507–524}} The key message in Haven's work is that the Black–Scholes–Merton equation is really a special case of the Schrödinger equation where markets are assumed to be efficient. The Schrödinger-based equation that Haven derives has a parameter ħ (not to be confused with the complex conjugate of h) that represents the amount of arbitrage that is present in the market resulting from a variety of sources including non-infinitely fast price changes, non-infinitely fast information dissemination and unequal wealth among traders. Haven argues that by setting this value appropriately, a more accurate option price can be derived, because in reality, markets are not truly efficient.

This is one of the reasons why it is possible that a quantum option pricing model could be more accurate than a classical one. Belal E. Baaquie has published many papers on quantum finance and even written a book that brings many of them together.{{cite book |year= 2002 |bibcode=2003npte.conf..333B |author1=Baaquie, Belal E. |author2=Coriano, Claudio |author3=Srikant, Marakani |page=8191 |arxiv=cond-mat/0208191 |doi=10.1142/9789812704467_0046|chapter= Quantum Mechanics, Path Integrals and Option Pricing: Reducing the Complexity of Finance |title=Nonlinear Physics – Theory and Experiment II |isbn=978-981-238-270-2 |s2cid=14095958 }}{{cite book|last=Baaquie|first=Belal|title=Quantum Finance: Path Integrals and Hamiltonians for Options and Interest Rates|year=2004|publisher=Cambridge University Press|isbn=978-0-521-84045-3|page=332}} Core to Baaquie's research and others like Matacz are Richard Feynman's path integrals.{{Cite journal |last=Matacz |first=Andrew |date=2002 |title=Path-dependent option pricing: the path integral partial averaging method |url=https://www.risk.net/journal-of-computational-finance/2160554/path-dependent-option-pricing-the-path-integral-partial-averaging-method |journal=The Journal of Computational Finance |volume=6 |issue=2 |pages=79–103 |doi=10.21314/JCF.2002.108 |arxiv=cond-mat/0005319 |access-date=2025-01-20 }}

Baaquie applies path integrals to several exotic options and presents analytical results comparing his results to the results of Black–Scholes–Merton equation showing that they are very similar. Edward Piotrowski et al. take a different approach by changing the Black–Scholes–Merton assumption regarding the behavior of the stock underlying the option.{{cite journal |title=Quantum extension of European option pricing based on the Ornstein Uhlenbeck process|year= 2006 |bibcode=2006PhyA..368..176P |author1=Piotrowski, Edward W. |author2=Schroeder, Małgorzata |author3=Zambrzycka, Anna |volume=368 |issue= 1 |pages=176–182 |journal=Physica A |doi=10.1016/j.physa.2005.12.021|arxiv = quant-ph/0510121 |s2cid= 14209173 }} Instead of assuming it follows a Wiener–Bachelier process,{{cite book | last = Hull | first = John | title = Options, futures, and other derivatives | publisher = Pearson/Prentice Hall | location = Upper Saddle River, N.J | year = 2006 | isbn = 978-0-13-149908-9 }} they assume that it follows an Ornstein–Uhlenbeck process.{{cite journal |first1=G. E. |last1=Uhlenbeck |first2=L. S. |last2=Ornstein |title=On the Theory of the Brownian Motion |journal=Phys. Rev. |year=1930 |volume=36 |issue=5 |pages=823–841 |doi=10.1103/PhysRev.36.823 |bibcode=1930PhRv...36..823U }} With this new assumption in place, they derive a quantum finance model as well as a European call option formula.

Other models such as Hull–White and Cox–Ingersoll–Ross have successfully used the same approach in the classical setting with interest rate derivatives.{{Cite journal |date=1990 |title=The pricing of options on interest rate caps and floors using the Hull–White model |journal=Advance Strategies in Risk Management}}{{cite journal |title=A theory of the term structure of interest rates|year= 1985|journal=Physica A}} Andrei Khrennikov builds on the work of Haven and others and further bolsters the idea that the market efficiency assumption made by the Black–Scholes–Merton equation may not be appropriate.{{cite arXiv |title=Classical and quantum randomness and the financial market|year= 2007 |author1=Khrennikov, Andrei|eprint=0704.2865 |class= q-fin.ST }} To support this idea, Khrennikov builds on a framework of contextual probabilities using agents as a way of overcoming criticism of applying quantum theory to finance. Luigi Accardi and Andreas Boukas again quantize the Black–Scholes–Merton equation, but in this case, they also consider the underlying stock to have both Brownian and Poisson processes.{{cite arXiv |title=The Quantum Black-Scholes Equation|author1=Accardi, Luigi |author2=Boukas, Andreas |eprint=0706.1300 |class=q-fin.PR |year=2007 }}

Quantum binomial model

Chen published a paper in 2001, where he presents a quantum binomial options pricing model or simply abbreviated as the quantum binomial model. Metaphorically speaking, Chen's quantum binomial options pricing model (referred to

hereafter as the quantum binomial model) is to existing quantum finance models what the Cox–Ross–Rubinstein classical binomial options pricing model was to the Black–Scholes–Merton model: a discretized and simpler version of the same result. These simplifications make the respective theories not only easier to analyze but also easier to implement on a computer.

= Multi-step quantum binomial model =

In the multi-step model the quantum pricing formula is:

:C_0^N=\mathrm{tr}[(\bigotimes_{j=1}^{N}\rho_j){[S_N-K]}^+],

which is the equivalent of the Cox–Ross–Rubinstein binomial options pricing model formula as follows:

:C_0^N=(1+r)^{-N}\sum_{n=0}^{N}\frac{N!}{n!(N-n)!}q^n{(1-q)}^{N-n}

{[S_0{(1+b)}^n{(1+a)}^{N-n}-K]}^+.

This shows that assuming stocks behave according to Maxwell–Boltzmann statistics, the quantum binomial model does indeed collapse to the classical binomial model.

Quantum volatility is as follows as per Keith Meyer:{{cite book|title=Extending and simulating the quantum binomial options pricing model|author=Keith Meyer|publisher=The University of Manitoba|url = http://mspace.lib.umanitoba.ca/handle/1993/3154 |year= 2009}}

:\sigma=\frac{\ln{(1+x_0+\sqrt{x_1^2+x_2^2+x_3^2})}}{\sqrt{1/t}}.

== Bose–Einstein assumption ==

Maxwell–Boltzmann statistics can be replaced by the quantum Bose–Einstein statistics resulting in the following option price formula:

:C_0^N=(1+r)^{-N}\sum_{n=0}^{N}\left(\frac{q^n{(1-q)}^{N-n}}{\sum_{k=0}^{N}q^k{(1-q)}^{N-k}}\right){[S_0{(1+b)}^n{(1+a)}^{N-n}-K]}^+.

The Bose–Einstein equation will produce option prices that will differ from those produced by the Cox–Ross–Rubinstein option

pricing formula in certain circumstances. This is because the stock is being treated like a quantum boson particle instead of a classical particle.

Quantum algorithm for the pricing of derivatives

Patrick Rebentrost showed in 2018 that an algorithm exists for quantum computers capable of pricing financial derivatives with a square root advantage over classical methods.{{Cite journal|last1=Rebentrost|first1=Patrick|last2=Gupt|first2=Brajesh|last3=Bromley|first3=Thomas R.|date=2018-04-30|title=Quantum computational finance: Monte Carlo pricing of financial derivatives|journal=Physical Review A|volume=98|issue=2|pages=022321|arxiv=1805.00109|bibcode=2018PhRvA..98b2321R|doi=10.1103/PhysRevA.98.022321|s2cid=73628234}} This development marks a shift from using quantum mechanics to gain insight into functional finance, to using quantum systems- quantum computers, to perform those calculations.

In 2020 David Orrell proposed an option-pricing model based on a quantum walk which can run on a photonics device.{{cite book |last=Orrell |first=David |author-link= David Orrell|date=2020 |title=Quantum Economics and Finance: An Applied Mathematics Introduction |location=New York |publisher=Panda Ohana |isbn=978-1916081611}}{{cite journal|last=Orrell|first=David| title=A quantum walk model of financial options |journal=Wilmott |year=2021| volume=2021 |issue=112 |pages=62–69|doi=10.1002/wilm.10918|s2cid=233850811}}{{cite news |author= |date= 6 November 2021|title= Schrödinger's markets |newspaper= The Economist}}

Criticism

In their review of Baaquie's work, Arioli and Valente point out that, unlike Schrödinger's equation, the Black-Scholes-Merton equation uses no imaginary numbers. Since quantum characteristics in physics like superposition and entanglement are a result of the imaginary numbers, Baaquie's numerical success must result from effects other than quantum ones.{{Cite journal |last1=Arioli |first1=Gianni |last2=Valente |first2=Giovanni |date=October 2021 |title=What Is Really Quantum in Quantum Econophysics? |url=https://www.cambridge.org/core/journals/philosophy-of-science/article/abs/what-is-really-quantum-in-quantum-econophysics/72BD63D409B4B073EC0076CAA2267643 |journal=Philosophy of Science |language=en |volume=88 |issue=4 |pages=665–685 |doi=10.1086/713921 |issn=0031-8248|url-access=subscription }}{{rp|668}} Rickles critiques Baaquies's work on economics grounds: empirical economic data are not random so they don't need a quantum randomness explanation.{{Cite journal |last=Rickles |first=Dean |date=December 2007 |title=Econophysics for philosophers |url=https://linkinghub.elsevier.com/retrieve/pii/S1355219807000202 |journal=Studies in History and Philosophy of Science Part B: Studies in History and Philosophy of Modern Physics |language=en |volume=38 |issue=4 |pages=948–978 |doi=10.1016/j.shpsb.2007.01.003|bibcode=2007SHPMP..38..948R |url-access=subscription }}{{rp|969}}

References

{{Reflist}}

Further reading

  • Belal E. Baaquie, [http://www.cambridge.org/gb/knowledge/isbn/item1171982/?site_locale=en_GB Quantum Finance: Path Integrals and Hamiltonians for Options and Interest Rates], Cambridge University Press (Cambridge, UK, 2004)
  • Belal E. Baaquie, [https://link.springer.com/book/10.1007/978-981-15-6611-0 Mathematical Methods and Quantum Mathematics for Economics and Finance], Springer (Singapore, 2020)

{{Finance}}

Category:Applied and interdisciplinary physics

Category:Mathematical finance

Category:Quantum information science

Category:Schools of economic thought

Category:Statistical mechanics

Category:Interdisciplinary subfields of economics