Vector measure

{{Use dmy dates|date=April 2022}}

In mathematics, a vector measure is a function defined on a family of sets and taking vector values satisfying certain properties. It is a generalization of the concept of finite measure, which takes nonnegative real values only.

Definitions and first consequences

Given a field of sets (\Omega, \mathcal F) and a Banach space X, a finitely additive vector measure (or measure, for short) is a function \mu:\mathcal {F} \to X such that for any two disjoint sets A and B in \mathcal{F} one has

\mu(A\cup B) =\mu(A) + \mu (B).

A vector measure \mu is called countably additive if for any sequence (A_i)_{i=1}^{\infty} of disjoint sets in \mathcal F such that their union is in \mathcal F it holds that

\mu{\left(\bigcup_{i=1}^\infty A_i\right)} = \sum_{i=1}^{\infty}\mu(A_i)

with the series on the right-hand side convergent in the norm of the Banach space X.

It can be proved that an additive vector measure \mu is countably additive if and only if for any sequence (A_i)_{i=1}^{\infty} as above one has

{{NumBlk||\lim_{n\to\infty} \left\|\mu{\left(\bigcup_{i=n}^\infty A_i\right)}\right\| = 0, |{{EquationRef|*}}}}

where \|\cdot\| is the norm on X.

Countably additive vector measures defined on sigma-algebras are more general than finite measures, finite signed measures, and complex measures, which are countably additive functions taking values respectively on the real interval [0, \infty), the set of real numbers, and the set of complex numbers.

Examples

Consider the field of sets made up of the interval [0, 1] together with the family \mathcal F of all Lebesgue measurable sets contained in this interval. For any such set A, define

\mu(A) = \chi_A

where \chi is the indicator function of A. Depending on where \mu is declared to take values, two different outcomes are observed.

  • \mu, viewed as a function from \mathcal F to the L^p-space L^\infty([0, 1]), is a vector measure which is not countably-additive.
  • \mu, viewed as a function from \mathcal F to the L^p-space L^1([0, 1]), is a countably-additive vector measure.

Both of these statements follow quite easily from the criterion ({{EquationNote|*}}) stated above.

The variation of a vector measure

Given a vector measure \mu : \mathcal{F} \to X, the variation |\mu| of \mu is defined as

|\mu|(A)=\sup \sum_{i=1}^n \|\mu(A_i)\|

where the supremum is taken over all the partitions

A = \bigcup_{i=1}^n A_i

of A into a finite number of disjoint sets, for all A in \mathcal{F}. Here, \|\cdot\| is the norm on X.

The variation of \mu is a finitely additive function taking values in [0, \infty]. It holds that

\|\mu(A)\| \leq |\mu|(A)

for any A in \mathcal{F}. If |\mu|(\Omega) is finite, the measure \mu is said to be of bounded variation. One can prove that if \mu is a vector measure of bounded variation, then \mu is countably additive if and only if |\mu| is countably additive.

Lyapunov's theorem

In the theory of vector measures, Lyapunov's theorem states that the range of a (non-atomic) finite-dimensional vector measure is closed and convex.Kluvánek, I., Knowles, G., Vector Measures and Control Systems, North-Holland Mathematics Studies 20, Amsterdam, 1976.{{cite book|last1=Diestel|first1=Joe| last2=Uhl|first2=Jerry J. Jr.|title=Vector measures|publisher=American Mathematical Society|location=Providence, R.I|year=1977|isbn=0-8218-1515-6}}{{Cite book|title=Functional analysis and control theory: Linear systems|last=Rolewicz |first=Stefan|year=1987| isbn=90-277-2186-6| publisher=D. Reidel Publishing Co.; PWN—Polish Scientific Publishers|oclc=13064804|edition=Translated from the Polish by Ewa Bednarczuk|series=Mathematics and its Applications (East European Series)|location=Dordrecht; Warsaw|volume=29|pages=xvi+524|mr=920371}} In fact, the range of a non-atomic vector measure is a zonoid (the closed and convex set that is the limit of a convergent sequence of zonotopes). It is used in economics,{{Cite book | last=Roberts|first=John |author-link=Donald John Roberts|chapter=Large economies|title=Contributions to the New Palgrave |editor=David M. Kreps|editor1-link=David M. Kreps|editor2=John Roberts|editor2-link=Donald John Roberts|editor3=Robert B. Wilson |editor3-link=Robert B. Wilson|date=July 1986|pages=30–35|url=https://gsbapps.stanford.edu/researchpapers/library/RP892.pdf |access-date=7 February 2011|series=Research paper|volume=892|publisher=Graduate School of Business, Stanford University |location=Palo Alto, CA|id=(Draft of articles for the first edition of New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics)}}{{cite journal|author-link=Robert Aumann|first=Robert J.|last=Aumann|title=Existence of competitive equilibrium in markets with a continuum of traders|journal=Econometrica|volume=34|number=1|date=January 1966 |pages=1–17 |jstor=1909854|mr=191623|doi=10.2307/1909854|s2cid=155044347 }} This paper builds on two papers by Aumann:

{{cite journal |title=Markets with a continuum of traders |journal=Econometrica |volume=32|number=1–2|date=January–April 1964|pages=39–50|jstor=1913732|mr=172689 |doi=10.2307/1913732 |last1=Aumann |first1=Robert J.}}

{{cite journal |title=Integrals of set-valued functions |journal=Journal of Mathematical Analysis and Applications|volume=12|number=1|date=August 1965|pages=1–12 | doi=10.1016/0022-247X(65)90049-1 |mr=185073|last1=Aumann|first1=Robert J.}}

{{cite news|last=Vind|first=Karl | date=May 1964|title=Edgeworth-allocations in an exchange economy with many traders|journal=International Economic Review | volume=5|pages=165–77|number=2|jstor=2525560}} Vind's article was noted by {{harvtxt|Debreu|1991|p=4}} with this comment:

The concept of a convex set (i.e., a set containing the segment connecting any two of its points) had repeatedly been placed at the center of economic theory before 1964. It appeared in a new light with the introduction of integration theory in the study of economic competition: If one associates with every agent of an economy an arbitrary set in the commodity space and if one averages those individual sets over a collection of insignificant agents, then the resulting set is necessarily convex. [Debreu appends this footnote: "On this direct consequence of a theorem of A. A. Lyapunov, see {{harvtxt|Vind|1964}}."] But explanations of the ... functions of prices ... can be made to rest on the convexity of sets derived by that averaging process. Convexity in the commodity space obtained by aggregation over a collection of insignificant agents is an insight that economic theory owes ... to integration theory. [Italics added]

{{cite news|title=The Mathematization of economic theory|first=Gérard|last=Debreu|author-link=Gérard Debreu|issue=Presidential address delivered at the 103rd meeting of the American Economic Association, 29 December 1990, Washington, DC | journal=The American Economic Review |volume=81, number 1|date=March 1991|pages=1–7|jstor=2006785}}

in ("bang–bang") control theory,{{cite book|title=Functional analysis and time optimal control|last1=Hermes|first1=Henry |last2=LaSalle|first2=Joseph P.|series=Mathematics in Science and Engineering|volume=56|publisher=Academic Press|location=New York—London|year=1969|pages=viii+136|mr=420366}} and in statistical theory.{{cite journal|last=Artstein|first=Zvi|title=Discrete and continuous bang-bang and facial spaces, or: Look for the extreme points|journal=SIAM Review|volume=22|year=1980|number=2|pages=172–185|doi=10.1137/1022026|jstor=2029960|mr=564562}}

Lyapunov's theorem has been proved by using the Shapley–Folkman lemma,{{cite journal|last=Tardella|first=Fabio|title=A new proof of the Lyapunov convexity theorem|journal=SIAM Journal on Control and Optimization|volume=28|year=1990|number=2| pages=478–481|doi=10.1137/0328026|mr=1040471}} which has been viewed as a discrete analogue of Lyapunov's theorem.{{cite book|last=Starr|first=Ross M.|author-link=Ross Starr|chapter=Shapley–Folkman theorem|title=The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics|editor-first=Steven N.|editor-last=Durlauf|editor2-first=Lawrence E. |editor2-last=Blume|publisher=Palgrave Macmillan|year=2008|edition=Second|pages=317–318 | url=http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_S000107|doi=10.1057/9780230226203.1518| isbn=978-0-333-78676-5}}Page 210: {{cite journal|last=Mas-Colell|first=Andreu|author-link=Andreu Mas-Colell|title=A note on the core equivalence theorem: How many blocking coalitions are there?|journal=Journal of Mathematical Economics| volume=5| year=1978| number=3| pages=207–215|doi=10.1016/0304-4068(78)90010-1|mr=514468}}

See also

  • {{annotated link|Bochner measurable function}}
  • {{annotated link|Bochner integral}}
  • {{annotated link|Bochner space}}
  • {{annotated link|Complex measure}}
  • {{annotated link|Signed measure}}
  • {{annotated link|Vector-valued functions}}
  • {{annotated link|Weakly measurable function}}

References

{{reflist|group=note}}

{{reflist}}

Bibliography

  • {{cite book|last=Cohn|first=Donald L.|title=Measure theory|place=Boston–Basel–Stuttgart|publisher=Birkhäuser Verlag|orig-year=1980|year=1997|edition=reprint|pages=IX+373|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=vRxV2FwJvoAC&q=Measure+theory+Cohn|zbl=0436.28001|isbn=3-7643-3003-1}}
  • {{cite book|last1 =Diestel|first1=Joe|last2 =Uhl|first2=Jerry J. Jr.|title =Vector measures|series=Mathematical Surveys|volume=15|publisher=American Mathematical Society|location=Providence, R.I|year=1977|pages=xiii+322|isbn=0-8218-1515-6}}
  • Kluvánek, I., Knowles, G, Vector Measures and Control Systems, North-Holland Mathematics Studies 20, Amsterdam, 1976.
  • {{springerEOM|title=Vector measures|id=Vector_measure|first=D. |last=van Dulst}}
  • {{cite book|last1=Rudin|first1=W|title=Functional analysis|url=https://archive.org/details/functionalanalys00rudi_320|url-access=limited|date=1973|publisher=McGraw-Hill|location=New York|page=[https://archive.org/details/functionalanalys00rudi_320/page/n123 114]|isbn=9780070542259}}

{{Analysis in topological vector spaces}}

{{Functional analysis}}

{{Measure theory}}

Category:Control theory

Category:Functional analysis

Category:Measures (measure theory)