elasticity of substitution

{{Short description|Economic metric}}

Elasticity of substitution is the ratio of percentage change in capital-labour ratio with the percentage change in Marginal Rate of Technical Substitution.{{cite book |author-link=Knut Sydsæter |last1=Sydsaeter |first1=Knut |last2=Hammond |first2=Peter |title=Mathematics for Economic Analysis |publisher=Prentice Hall |year=1995 |pages=561–562 }} In a competitive market, it measures the percentage change in the two inputs used in response to a percentage change in their prices.Bergstrom, Ted (2015). [http://www.econ.ucsb.edu/~tedb/Courses/GraduateTheoryUCSB/elasticity_of_substitution2015.pdf Lecture Notes on Elasticity of Substitution], p. 5. Viewed June 17, 2016. It gives a measure of the curvature of an isoquant, and thus, the substitutability between inputs (or goods), i.e. how easy it is to substitute one input (or good) for the other.{{cite journal |first=Olivier |last=de La Grandville |title=Curvature and elasticity of substitution: Straightening it out |journal=Journal of Economics |year=1997 |volume=66 |issue=1 |pages=23–34 |doi=10.1007/BF01231465 |s2cid=154023144 }}

History of the concept

John Hicks introduced the concept in 1932. Joan Robinson independently discovered it in 1933 using a mathematical formulation that was equivalent to Hicks's, though that was not implemented at the time.Chirinko, Robert (2006). [http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0164070407001619 Sigma: The Long and Short of It]. Journal of Macroeconomics. 2: 671-86.

Definition

The general definition of the elasticity of X with respect to Y is E^X_Y = \frac{\%\ \mbox{change in X}}{\%\ \mbox{change in Y}}, which reduces to E^X_Y = \frac{dX}{dY} \frac{Y}{X} for infinitesimal changes and differentiable variables. The elasticity of substitution is the change in the ratio of the use of two goods with respect to the ratio of their marginal values or prices. The most common application is to the ratio of capital (K) and labor (L) used with respect to the ratio of their marginal products MP_K and MP_L or of the rental price (r) and the wage (w). Another application is to the ratio of consumption goods 1 and 2 with respect to the ratio of their marginal utilities or their prices. We will start with the consumption application.

Let the utility over consumption be given by U(c_1,c_2) and let U_{c_i}= \partial U(c_1,c_2)/\partial {c_i}. Then the elasticity of substitution is:

: E_{21} =\frac{d \ln (c_2/c_1) }{d \ln (MRS_{12})}

=\frac{d \ln (c_2/c_1) }{d \ln (U_{c_1}/U_{c_2})}

=\frac{\frac{d (c_2/c_1) }{c_2/c_1}}{\frac{d (U_{c_1}/U_{c_2})}{U_{c_1}/U_{c_2}}}

=\frac{\frac{d (c_2/c_1) }{c_2/c_1}}{\frac{d (p_1/p_2)}{p_1/p_2}}

where MRS is the marginal rate of substitution. (These differentials are taken along the isoquant that passes through the base point. That is, the inputs c_1 and c_2 are not varied independently, but instead one input is varied freely while the other input is constrained to lie on the isoquant that passes through the base point. Because of this constraint, the MRS and the ratio of inputs are one-to-one functions of each other under suitable convexity assumptions.) The last equality presents MRS_{12} = p_1/p_2 , where p_1, p_2 are the prices of goods 1 and 2. This is a relationship from the first order condition for a consumer utility maximization problem in Arrow–Debreu interior equilibrium, where the marginal utilities of two goods are proportional to prices. Intuitively we are looking at how a consumer's choices over consumption items change as their relative prices change.

Note also that E_{21} = E_{12}:

: E_{21} =\frac{d \ln (c_2/c_1) }{d \ln (U_{c_1}/U_{c_2})}

=\frac{d \left(-\ln (c_2/c_1)\right) }{d \left(-\ln (U_{c_1}/U_{c_2})\right)}

=\frac{d \ln (c_1/c_2) }{d \ln (U_{c_2}/U_{c_1})}

= E_{12}

An equivalent characterization of the elasticity of substitution is:Given that:

:\ \frac{d (x_2/x_1)}{x_2/x_1} = d\log (x_2/x_1) = d\log x_2 - d\log x_1 = - (d\log x_1 - d\log x_2) = - d\log (x_1/x_2) = - \frac{d (x_1/x_2)}{x_1/x_2}

an equivalent way to define the elasticity of substitution is:

:\ \sigma =-\frac{d (c_1/c_2)}{d MRS}\frac{MRS}{c_1/c_2}=-\frac{d\log (c_1/c_2)}{d\log MRS}.

: E_{21} =\frac{d \ln (c_2/c_1) }{d \ln (MRS_{12})}

=-\frac{d \ln (c_2/c_1) }{d \ln (MRS_{21})}

=-\frac{d \ln (c_2/c_1) }{d \ln (U_{c_2}/U_{c_1})}

=-\frac{\frac{d (c_2/c_1) }{c_2/c_1}}{\frac{d (U_{c_2}/U_{c_1})}{U_{c_2}/U_{c_1}}}

=-\frac{\frac{d (c_2/c_1) }{c_2/c_1}}{\frac{d (p_2/p_1)}{p_2/p_1}}

In discrete-time models, the elasticity of substitution of consumption in periods t and t+1 is known as elasticity of intertemporal substitution.

Similarly, if the production function is f(x_1,x_2) then the elasticity of substitution is:

: \sigma_{21} =\frac{d \ln (x_2/x_1) }{d \ln MRTS_{12}}

=\frac{d \ln (x_2/x_1) }{d \ln (\frac{df}{dx_1}/\frac{df}{dx_2})}

=\frac{\frac{d (x_2/x_1) }{x_2/x_1}}{\frac{d (\frac{df}{dx_1}/\frac{df}{dx_2})}{\frac{df}{dx_1}/\frac{df}{dx_2}}}

=-\frac{\frac{d (x_2/x_1) }{x_2/x_1}}{\frac{d (\frac{df}{dx_2}/\frac{df}{dx_1})}{\frac{df}{dx_2}/\frac{df}{dx_1}}}

where MRTS is the marginal rate of technical substitution.

The inverse of elasticity of substitution is elasticity of complementarity.

Example

Consider Cobb–Douglas production function f(x_1,x_2)=x_1^a x_2^{1-a}.

The marginal rate of technical substitution is

:MRTS_{21} = \frac{1-a}{a} \frac{x_1}{x_2}

It is convenient to change the notations. Denote

:\frac{1-a}{a} \frac{x_1}{x_2}=\theta

Rewriting this we have

:\frac{x_1}{x_2} = \frac{a}{1-a}\theta

Then the elasticity of substitution is{{Cite web|url=https://eric-roca.github.io/courses/mathematical_appendix/elasticity_of_substitution/|title=Elasticity of substitution|date=21 May 2025}}

:\sigma_{21} = \frac{d \ln (\frac{x_1}{x_2})}{d \ln (MRTS_{21})} = \frac{d \ln (\frac{x_1}{x_2})}{d \ln (\theta)} = \frac{d \frac{x_1}{x_2}}{\frac{x_1}{x_2}} \frac{\theta}{d \theta} = \frac{d \frac{x_1}{x_2}}{d \theta} \frac{\theta}{\frac{x_1}{x_2}} = \frac{a}{1-a} \frac{1-a}{a} \frac{x_1}{x_2} \frac{x_2}{x_1} = 1

Economic interpretation

Given an original allocation/combination and a specific substitution on allocation/combination for the original one, the larger the magnitude of the elasticity of substitution (the marginal rate of substitution elasticity of the relative allocation) means the more likely to substitute. There are always 2 sides to the market; here we are talking about the receiver, since the elasticity of preference is that of the receiver.

The elasticity of substitution also governs how the relative expenditure on goods or factor inputs changes as relative prices change. Let S_{21} denote expenditure on c_2 relative to that on c_1. That is:

: S_{21} \equiv \frac{p_2 c_2}{p_1 c_1}

As the relative price p_2/p_1 changes, relative expenditure changes according to:

: \frac{dS_{21}}{d\left(p_2/p_1\right)} = \frac{c_2}{c_1} + \frac{p_2}{p_1}\cdot\frac{d\left(c_2/c_1\right)}{d\left(p_2/p_1\right)}

= \frac{c_2}{c_1}\left[1 + \frac{d\left(c_2/c_1\right)}{d\left(p_2/p_1\right)}\cdot\frac{p_2/p_1}{c_2/c_1} \right]

= \frac{c_2}{c_1}\left(1 - E_{21} \right)

Thus, whether or not an increase in the relative price of c_2 leads to an increase or decrease in the relative expenditure on c_2 depends on whether the elasticity of substitution is less than or greater than one.

Intuitively, the direct effect of a rise in the relative price of c_2 is to increase expenditure on c_2, since a given quantity of c_2 is more costly. On the other hand, assuming the goods in question are not Giffen goods, a rise in the relative price of c_2 leads to a fall in relative demand for c_2, so that the quantity of c_2 purchased falls, which reduces expenditure on c_2.

Which of these effects dominates depends on the magnitude of the elasticity of substitution. When the elasticity of substitution is less than one, the first effect dominates: relative demand for c_2 falls, but by proportionally less than the rise in its relative price, so that relative expenditure rises. In this case, the goods are gross complements.

Conversely, when the elasticity of substitution is greater than one, the second effect dominates: the reduction in relative quantity exceeds the increase in relative price, so that relative expenditure on c_2 falls. In this case, the goods are gross substitutes.

Note that when the elasticity of substitution is exactly one (as in the Cobb–Douglas case), expenditure on c_2 relative to c_1 is independent of the relative prices.

See also

Notes

{{Reflist}}

References

  • {{cite book |author-link=John Hicks |first=J. R. |last=Hicks |year=1932 |title=The Theory of Wages |publisher=Macmillan |title-link=The Theory of Wages }}
  • {{cite book |author-link=Andreu Mas-Colell |last1=Mas-Colell |first1=Andreu |last2=Whinston |last3=Green |year=2007 |title=Microeconomic Theory |publisher=Oxford University Press |location=New York, NY |isbn=978-0195073409 }}
  • {{cite book |author-link=Hal Varian |first=Hal |last=Varian |title=Microeconomic Analysis |edition=3rd |year=1992 |publisher=W.W. Norton & Company |isbn=978-0-393-95735-8 |url-access=registration |url=https://archive.org/details/microeconomicana00vari_0 }}
  • {{cite journal |first1=Rainer |last1=Klump |first2=Peter |last2=McAdam |first3=Alpo |last3=Willman |year=2007 |title=Factor Substitution and Factor-Augmenting Technical Progress in the United States: A Normalized Supply-Side System Approach |journal=Review of Economics and Statistics |volume=89 |issue=1 |pages=183–192 |doi=10.1162/rest.89.1.183 |s2cid=57570638 }}