inflation targeting
{{Short description|Monetary policy on interest rates}}
{{Use dmy dates|date=January 2020}}
In macroeconomics, inflation targeting is a monetary policy where a central bank follows an explicit target for the inflation rate for the medium-term and announces this inflation target to the public. The assumption is that the best that monetary policy can do to support long-term growth of the economy is to maintain price stability, and price stability is achieved by controlling inflation. The central bank uses interest rates as its main short-term monetary instrument.{{Cite news|issue=The New Fed |last=Coy |first=Peter |title=What's The Fuss Over Inflation Targeting? |work=BusinessWeek |date=7 November 2005 |url=http://www.businessweek.com/magazine/content/05_45/b3958607.htm |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20110728124345/http://www.businessweek.com/magazine/content/05_45/b3958607.htm |archive-date=28 July 2011 }}{{cite web |url=http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/basics/target.htm |title =Inflation Targeting: Holding the Line |last=Jahan |first=Sarwat |publisher=International Monetary Funds, Finance & Development |access-date=28 December 2014}}{{Cite EB1922 |last=Fisher |first=Irving |authorlink=Irving Fisher |wstitle=Dollar Stabilization }}
An inflation-targeting central bank will raise or lower interest rates based on above-target or below-target inflation, respectively. The conventional wisdom is that raising interest rates usually cools the economy to rein in inflation; lowering interest rates usually accelerates the economy, thereby boosting inflation. The first three countries to implement fully-fledged inflation targeting were New Zealand, Canada and the United Kingdom in the early 1990s, although Germany had adopted many elements of inflation targeting earlier.
History
Early proposals of monetary systems targeting the price level or the inflation rate, rather than the exchange rate, followed the general crisis of the gold standard after World War I. Irving Fisher proposed a "compensated dollar" system in which the gold content in paper money would vary with the price of goods in terms of gold, so that the price level in terms of paper money would stay fixed. Fisher's proposal was a first attempt to target prices while retaining the automatic functioning of the gold standard. In his Tract on Monetary Reform (1923), John Maynard Keynes advocated what we would now call an inflation targeting scheme. In the context of sudden inflations and deflations in the international economy right after World War I, Keynes recommended a policy of exchange-rate flexibility, appreciating the currency as a response to international inflation and depreciating it when there are international deflationary forces, so that internal prices remained more or less stable. Interest in inflation targeting waned during the Bretton Woods era (1944–1971), as they were inconsistent with the exchange rate pegs that prevailed during three decades after World War II.
=New Zealand, Canada, United Kingdom=
Inflation targeting was pioneered in New Zealand in 1990.{{cite book|author1=Andrew G. Haldane| title=Targeting Inflation: A Conference of Central Banks on the Use of Inflation Targets Organised by the Bank of England, 9-10 March 1995|date=1995|publisher=Bank of England|location=London |isbn=9781857300734| author1-link=Andy Haldane}} Canada was the second country to formally adopt inflation targeting in February 1991.
The United Kingdom adopted inflation targeting in October 1992 after exiting the European Exchange Rate Mechanism.{{cite web|title=Inflation Targeting Has Been A Successful Monetary Policy Strategy|url=https://www.nber.org/digest/apr98/w6126.html|publisher=NBER|access-date=31 October 2016}}{{cite web|title=Targeting Inflation: The United Kingdom in Retrospect|url=https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/seminar/2000/targets/strach7.pdf|publisher=IMF|access-date=31 October 2016}} The Bank of England's Monetary Policy Committee was given sole responsibility in 1998 for setting interest rates to meet the Government's Retail Prices Index (RPI) inflation target of 2.5%.{{cite web |title=Key Monetary Policy Dates Since 1990 |publisher=Bank of England |access-date=20 September 2007 |url=http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/monetarypolicy/history.htm |archive-url = https://web.archive.org/web/20070629143630/http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/monetarypolicy/history.htm |archive-date = 29 June 2007}} The target changed to 2% in December 2003 when the Consumer Price Index (CPI) replaced the Retail Prices Index as the UK Treasury's inflation index.{{cite web |title=Remit of the Monetary Policy Committee of the Bank of England and the New Inflation Target |publisher=HM Treasury |access-date=20 September 2007 |date=10 December 2003 |url=http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/monetarypolicy/pdf/chancellorletter031210.pdf| archive-url= https://web.archive.org/web/20070926052337/http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/monetarypolicy/pdf/chancellorletter031210.pdf| archive-date= 26 September 2007 | url-status= live}} If inflation overshoots or undershoots the target by more than 1%, the Governor of the Bank of England is required to write a letter to the Chancellor of the Exchequer explaining why, and how he will remedy the situation.{{cite web|title=Monetary Policy Framework|url=http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/monetarypolicy/Pages/framework/framework.aspx|publisher=Bank of England|access-date=31 October 2016}}{{cite web|title=CCBS Lecture Series - Inflation Targeting: The British Experience|url=http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/education/Pages/ccbs/ls/lshb01.aspx|publisher=Bank of England|access-date=31 October 2016|date=January 1999|archive-date=31 October 2016|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20161031212111/http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/education/Pages/ccbs/ls/lshb01.aspx|url-status=dead}}{{cite news|title=Inflation targeting is 25 years old, but has it worked?|url=https://www.bbc.co.uk/news/31559074|access-date=31 October 2016|work=BBC|date=11 March 2015|postscript=none}}; {{cite news|title=Why do we target 2pc inflation? (And does it matter if we keep missing it?)|url=https://www.telegraph.co.uk/finance/bank-of-england/11675526/Why-do-we-target-2pc-inflation-And-does-it-matter-we-keep-missing-it.html|access-date=31 October 2016|work=The Telegraph|date=16 June 2015}} The success of inflation targeting in the United Kingdom has been attributed to the Bank's focus on transparency. The Bank of England has been a leader in producing innovative ways of communicating information to the public, especially through its Inflation Report, which have been emulated by many other central banks.
Inflation targeting then spread to other advanced economies in the 1990s and began to spread to emerging markets beginning in the 2000s.
=European Central Bank=
Although the ECB does not consider itself to be an inflation-targeting central bank,{{cite web|author1=Governor Laurence H. Meyer|title=Inflation Targets and Inflation Targeting|url=https://www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/speeches/2001/20010717/|publisher=The Federal Reserve Board|access-date=1 December 2016|date=17 July 2001}} after the inception of the euro in January 1999, the objective of the European Central Bank (ECB) has been to maintain price stability within the Eurozone.wikisource consolidation The Governing Council of the ECB in October 1998THE EUROPEAN CENTRAL BANK HISTORY, ROLE AND FUNCTIONS BY HANSPETER K. SCHELLER SECOND REVISED EDITION 2006, {{ISBN|92-899-0022-9}} (print) {{ISBN|92-899-0027-X}} (online) page 81 at the pdf online version defined price stability as inflation of under 2%, "a year-on-year increase in the Harmonised Index of Consumer Prices (HICP) for the euro area of below 2%" and added that price stability "was to be maintained over the medium term".{{cite web | title=Powers and responsibilities of the European Central Bank | publisher=European Central Bank | url=http://www.ecb.int/ecb/orga/tasks/html/index.en.html | access-date=10 March 2009 | url-status=dead | archive-date=16 December 2008 | archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20081216083913/http://www.ecb.int/ecb/orga/tasks/html/index.en.html }} The Governing Council confirmed this definition in May 2003 following a thorough evaluation of the ECB's monetary policy strategy. On that occasion, the Governing Council clarified that "in the pursuit of price stability, it aims to maintain inflation rates below, but close to, 2% over the medium term". Since then, the numerical target of 2% has become common for major developed economies, including the United States (since January 2012) and Japan (since January 2013).{{cite journal|last1=Noyer|first1=Christian|title=Thoughts on the zero lower bound in relation with monetary and financial stability|url=https://www.bis.org/review/r160115c.htm?ql=1|publisher=Bank for International Settlements|access-date=18 January 2016|date=12 January 2016}}
In 8 July 2021, the ECB changed its inflation target to a symmetrical 2% over the medium term. Symmetry in the inflation target means that the Governing Council considers negative and positive deviations of inflation from the target to be equally undesirable.{{cite journal |title=An overview of the ECB's monetary policy strategy |url=https://www.ecb.europa.eu/home/search/review/html/ecb.strategyreview_monpol_strategy_overview.en.html |website=European Central Bank |date=8 July 2021 |access-date=19 January 2024 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20240119024415/https://www.ecb.europa.eu/home/search/review/html/ecb.strategyreview_monpol_strategy_overview.en.html |archive-date=19 January 2024}}
=Emerging markets=
In 2000, Frederic S. Mishkin concluded that "although inflation targeting is not a panacea and may not be appropriate for many emerging market countries, it can be a highly useful monetary policy strategy in a number of them".
==Armenia==
The Central Bank of Armenia (CBA) announced in 2006 that it will implement an inflation targeting strategy. The process of full transition to inflation targeting was supposed to end in 2008. Operational, macroeconomic and institutional preconditions for inflation targeting should have been met to ensure a full transition. CBA believes that it has managed to meet all the preconditions successfully and should concentrate on building a public trust in the new monetary policy regime. A specific model has been developed to estimate CBA's reaction function and the results showed that the inertia of inflation rate and interest rate are most vital in the reaction function. This can be an evidence that the announcement of the strategy is a trustworthy commitment. There are people who claim that inflation targeting is too restrictive for dealing with positive supply shocks. On the other hand, the IMF claims that inflation targeting strategy is good for developing economies, however it requires a lot of information for forecasting.Kemme, David & Banaian, King & Sargsyan, Grigor. (2008). [https://www.researchgate.net/publication/5219082%20Inflation%20Targeting%20in%20Armenia%20Monetary%20Policy%20in%20Transition Inflation Targeting in Armenia: Monetary Policy in Transition.] Comparative Economic Studies. 50. 421-437. 10.1057/ces.2008.22.
The Central Bank continued to pursue a policy of tightening monetary conditions during the reporting period, increasing the policy interest rate by a total of 2.75 percentage points. At the same time, about half of the tightening, 1.25 percentage points, was carried out in 2022 in March, reacting to the high inflation situation formed in the case of unprecedented uncertainties.{{cite web |title=Inflation report |url=https://www.cba.am/Storage/EN/publications/Gnach/Monetary%20overview_III_2022.pdf?fbclid=IwAR1y39vBEalR8G5y53bS0yabd1yIoAyOnvFqebGBTYROqd6W0OvWuOWG0lY |website=cba.am |publisher=Central Bank of Armenia |access-date=11 December 2022}}
Being constantly hit by external shocks to the national economy over the past three years, Armenia is still on the path of recovery thanks to economic management efforts. According to the 3-year Stand-By Arrangement, which came to its end on May 16, 2022, important structural and institutional reforms have been implemented. Those include improvement of tax compliance, budget process refinement, strengthening the stability of financial sector and most importantly fostering the inflation targeting framework.INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND. [https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/CR/Issues/2022/05/03/Republic-of-Armenia-Sixth-Review-under-the-Stand-by-Arrangement-Press-Release-and-Staff-517511 Republic of Armenia: Sixth Review under the Stand-by Arrangement-Press Release]; and Staff Report.
==Chile==
{{further|Inflation in Chile}}
In Chile, a 20% inflation rate pushed the Central Bank of Chile to announce at the end of 1990 an inflation objective for the annual inflation rate for the year ending in December 1991.{{cite journal |author-link=Frederic S. Mishkin |first=Frederic S. |last=Mishkin |title=Inflation Targeting in Emerging-Market Countries |journal=American Economic Review |volume=90 |issue=2 |year=2000 |pages=105–109 |doi=10.1257/aer.90.2.105 |s2cid=16768021 |url=http://www.nber.org/papers/w7618.pdf }} However, Chile was not regarded as a fully-fledged inflation targeter until October 1999.{{Cite journal|title=A Quince Años de las Metas de Inflación en Chile|volume=48 |trans-title=Fifteen Years into the Implementation of Fully-fledged Inflation Targeting in Chile |date=2014-05-01 |url=https://www.bcentral.cl/documents/33528/133323/bcch_archivo_096594_es.pdf/caaf125f-1dd6-9042-6ba5-3a809e0cf050?t=1573270009283 |last=García Silva |first=Pablo |publisher=Central Bank of Chile|journal=Economic Policy Papers of the Central Bank of Chile |language=Spanish}} According to Pablo García Silva, member of the board of the Central Bank of Chile, this has allowed to attenuate inflation. García Silva exemplifies this with the limited inflation seen in Chile during the 2002 Brazilian general election and the Great Recession of 2008–2009.
==Czech Republic==
The Czech National Bank (CNB) is an example of an inflation targeting central bank in a small open economy with a recent history of economic transition and real convergence to its Western European peers. Since 2010 the CNB uses 2 percent with a +/- 1pp range around it as the inflation target.See the [https://www.cnb.cz/en/ Czech National Bank's website] The CNB places a lot of emphasis on transparency and communication; indeed, a recent study of more than 100 central banks found the CNB to be among the four most transparent ones.N. Nergiz Dincer and Barry Eichengreen (2014): [http://www.ijcb.org/journal/ijcb14q1a6.pdf "Central Bank Transparency and Independence: Updates and New Measures"], International Journal of Central Banking, March 2014, pp. 189-253.
In 2012, inflation was expected to fall well below the target, leading the CNB to gradually reduce the level of its basic monetary policy instrument, the 2-week repo rate, until the zero lower bound (actually 0.05 percent) was reached in late 2012. In light of the threat of a further fall in inflation and possibly even of a protracted period of deflation, on 7 November 2013 the CNB declared an immediate commitment to weaken the exchange rate to the level of 27 Czech korunas per 1 euro (day-on-day weakening by about 5 percent) and to keep the exchange rate from getting stronger than this value until at least the end of 2014 (later on this was changed to the second half of 2016). The CNB thus decided to use the exchange rate as a supplementary tool to make sure that inflation returns to the 2 percent target level. Such a use of the exchange rate as tool within the regime of inflation targeting should not be confused with a fixed exchange-rate system or with a currency war.Ali Alichi, Jaromir Benes, Joshua Felman, Irene Feng, Charles Freedman, Douglas Laxton, Evan Tanner, David Vavra, and Hou Wang (2015): [http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2015/wp1574.pdf "Frontiers of Monetary Policymaking: Adding the Exchange Rate as a Tool to Combat Deflationary Risks in the Czech Republic"], International Monetary Fund, Working Paper No. 15/74.Michal Franta, Tomas Holub, Petr Kral, Ivana Kubicova, Katerina Smidkova, Borek Vasicek (2014): [http://www.cnb.cz/en/research/research_publications/irpn/download/rpn_3_2014.pdf "The Exchange Rate as an Instrument at Zero Interest Rates: The Case of the Czech Republic"], Czech National Bank, Research and Policy Note No. 3/2014.Skorepa, M., and Hampl, M. (2014): [http://www.bis.org/publ/bppdf/bispap78j.pdf "Evolution of the Czech National Bank’s holdings of foreign exchange reserves"], BIS Papers No. 78, pp. 159-169.
=United States=
In a historic shift on 25 January 2012, U.S. Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke set a 2% target inflation rate, bringing the Fed in line with many of the world's other major central banks.{{cite web|title=Why does the Federal Reserve aim for 2 percent inflation over time?|url=http://www.federalreserve.gov/faqs/economy_14400.htm| website =The Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System|access-date=8 March 2015}} Until then, the Fed's policy committee, the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC), did not have an explicit inflation target but regularly announced a desired target range for inflation (usually between 1.7% and 2%) measured by the personal consumption expenditures price index.
Prior to adoption of the target, some people argued that an inflation target would give the Fed too little flexibility to stabilise growth and/or employment in the event of an external economic shock. Another criticism was that an explicit target might turn central bankers into what Mervyn King, former Governor of the Bank of England, had in 1997 colorfully termed "inflation nutters"As quoted on page 158 of Poole, W. (2006), "Inflation targeting", speech delivered to Junior Achievement of Arkansas, Inc., Little Rock, Arkansas, 16 February 2006. Published in Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, vol. 88, no. 3 (May–June 2006), pp. 155-164.—that is, central bankers who concentrate on the inflation target to the detriment of stable growth, employment, and/or exchange rates. King went on to help design the Bank's inflation targeting policy,{{Cite news | last = Fraher | first = John | title = King May Be More Irritant Than Ally for Brown at BOE | work = Bloomberg Exclusive | access-date = 5 August 2008 | date = 5 June 2008 | url = https://www.bloomberg.com/apps/news?pid=20601109&sid=aKgvGtKRV1IU&refer=home}} and asserts that the buffoonery has not actually happened, as did Chairman of the U.S. Federal Reserve Ben Bernanke, who stated in 2003 that all inflation targeting at the time was of a flexible variety, in theory and practice.{{Cite conference |conference=Annual Washington Policy Conference of the National Association of Business Economists |last=Bernanke |first=Ben S. |title=A Perspective on Inflation Targeting |location=Washington, D.C. |date=25 March 2003 |url=http://www.federalreserve.gov/Boarddocs/Speeches/2003/20030325/default.htm}}
Former Chairman Alan Greenspan, as well as other former FOMC members such as Alan Blinder, typically agreed with the benefits of inflation targeting, but were reluctant to accept the loss of freedom involved; Bernanke, however, was a well-known advocate.Ben S. Bernanke and Frederic S. Mishkin, (1997), [https://www0.gsb.columbia.edu/faculty/fmishkin/PDFpapers/w5893.pdf "Inflation targeting: a new framework for monetary policy?"], The Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol. 11, no. 2 (Spring 1997), pp. 97-116.
In August 2020, the FOMC released a revised Statement on Longer-Run Goals and Monetary Policy Strategy.{{cite web |title=Review of Monetary Policy Strategy, Tools, and Communications |url=https://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/review-of-monetary-policy-strategy-tools-and-communications.htm |website=www.federalreserve.gov |publisher=Federal Reserve |access-date=17 April 2022}} The review announced the FED would seek to achieve inflation that 'averages' 2% over time. In practice this means that following periods when inflation has been running persistently below 2 percent, appropriate monetary policy will likely aim to achieve inflation moderately above 2 percent for some time.{{cite web |title=2020 Statement on Longer-Run Goals and Monetary Policy Strategy |url=https://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/review-of-monetary-policy-strategy-tools-and-communications-statement-on-longer-run-goals-monetary-policy-strategy.htm |website=www.federalreserve.gov |publisher=Federal Reserve |access-date=17 April 2022}} This way, the fed hopes to better anchor longer-term inflation expectations, which they say would foster price stability and moderate long-term interest rates and enhance the Committee's ability to promote maximum employment in the face of significant economic disturbances.
Theoretical questions
{{Research paper|date=November 2017}}
New classical macroeconomics and rational expectations hypothesis can explain how and why inflation targeting works. Expectations of firms (or the subjective probability distribution of outcomes) will be around the prediction of the theory itself (the objective probability distribution of those outcomes) for the same information set.{{cite journal |first=John F. |last=Muth |year=1961 |title=Rational Expectations and the Theory of Price Movements |journal=Econometrica |volume=29 |issue=3 |pages=315–335 |jstor=1909635 |doi=10.2307/1909635 }} So, rational agents expect the most probable outcome to emerge. However, there is limited success at specifying the relevant model, and the full and perfect knowledge of a given macroeconomic system can be regarded as a comfortable presumption at best. Knowledge of the relevant model is not feasible, even if high-level econometrical techniques were accessible or adequate identification of the relevant explanatory variables were performed. So, estimation bias depends on the quantity and quality of information to which the modeller has access. In other words, estimations are asymptotically unbiased with respect to the exploited information.
Meanwhile, consistency can be interpreted similarly. On the basis of asymptotical unbiasedness, a moderated version of the rational expectations hypothesis can be suggested in which familiarity with the theoretical parameters is not a requirement for the relevant model. An agent with access to sufficiently vast, quality information and high-level methodological skills could specify its own quasi-relevant model describing a specific macroeconomic system. By increasing the amount of information processed, this agent could further reduce its bias. If this agent were also focal, such as a central bank, then other agents would likely accept the proposed model and adjust their expectations accordingly. In this way, individual expectations become unbiased as much as possible, albeit against a background of considerable passivity. According to some researches, this is the theoretical background of the functionality of inflation targeting regimes.{{cite book |last=Galbács |first=Peter |chapter=The Rational Expectations Hypothesis as a Key Element of New Classical Macroeconomics |pages=53–90 |title= The Theory of New Classical Macroeconomics. A Positive Critique |location= Heidelberg/New York/Dordrecht/London |publisher=Springer |year=2015 |isbn= 978-3-319-17578-2|doi=10.1007/978-3-319-17578-2|series=Contributions to Economics }}
Empirical issues
= Forward looking in inflation targeting =
The Federal Reserve and other central banks typically employ a forward-looking approach when targeting inflation, focusing on expected future inflation rather than current levels. Clarida, Galí, and Gertler (2000){{cite journal|author1=Richard Clarida|author2=Jordi Galí|author3=Mark Gertler|title=Monetary policy rules and macroeconomic stability: Evidence and some theory|journal=The Quarterly Journal of Economics|date=2000|volume=115|issue=1|pages=147-180|doi=10.1162/003355300554692|hdl=10230/1217|hdl-access=free}} developed an influential model showing that the Fed's policy decisions respond primarily to forecasted inflation, not just to current economic conditions, establishing a key theoretical foundation for forward-looking monetary policy frameworks. Bernanke and Woodford (1997){{cite journal|author1=Ben S. Bernanke|author2=Michael Woodford|title=Inflation forecasts and monetary policy|journal=Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking|date=1997|volume=29|issue=4|pages=653-684|doi=10.2307/2953657}} further demonstrated that effective monetary policy must incorporate forecasts of future inflation while avoiding circularity problems that arise when policy depends too heavily on private sector expectations, offering crucial insights into the practical implementation of forward-looking inflation targeting. Chen and Valcarcel{{Cite journal |last1=Chen |first1=Zhengyang |last2=Valcarcel |first2=Victor J. |date=January 2025 |title=Modeling inflation expectations in forward-looking interest rate and money growth rules |journal=Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control |language=en |volume=170|pages=104999 |doi=10.1016/j.jedc.2024.104999| issn=0165-1889|doi-access=free }} finds targeting inflation expectations in an otherwise standard Taylor-rule-type policy reaction function better characterize the monetary policy actions in macroeconomic modeling.
= Target band size =
While most inflation targeting countries set their target band at 2 percentage points, the band sizes are wide-ranging across countries and inflation targeters frequently update their target bands.{{Cite web |title=Do Actions Speak Louder Than Words? Assessing the Effects of Inflation Targeting Track Records on Macroeconomic Performance |url=https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/WP/Issues/2022/11/11/Do-Actions-Speak-Louder-Than-Words-Assessing-the-Effects-of-Inflation-Targeting-Track-525070 |access-date=2023-01-08 |website=IMF |language=en}}For instance, Australia has set an inflation target band between 2 percent and 3 percent, while South Africa has a target band of 3 percentage points between 3 percent and 6 percent.
= Track record =
Inflation targeting countries' track records in maintaining inflation within the central banks' target bands differ substantially and financial markets differentiate inflation targeters by behaviors.{{Cite web |title=Stock Returns and Inflation Redux: An Explanation from Monetary Policy in Advanced and Emerging Markets |url=https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/WP/Issues/2021/08/20/Stock-Returns-and-Inflation-Redux-An-Explanation-from-Monetary-Policy-in-Advanced-and-463391 |access-date=2023-01-08 |website=IMF |language=en}} Inflation targeting track records have varied and lasting impacts on asset prices such as stock returns, bond yields, and exchange rates. Consequently, credible inflation targeting countries enjoy enhanced monetary policy transmission and save fiscal space.{{Cite journal |last=Zhang |first=Zhongxia |date=2025-06-01 |title=Does inflation targeting track record matter for asset prices? Evidence from stock, bond, and foreign exchange markets |url=https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S1042443125000319 |journal=Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money |volume=101 |pages=102141 |doi=10.1016/j.intfin.2025.102141 |issn=1042-4431|doi-access=free }}
Debate
There is some empirical evidence that inflation targeting does what its advocates claim, that is, making the outcomes, if not the process, of monetary policy more transparent.{{cite book|last1=Bernanke|first1=Ben S.|last2=Laubach|first2=Thomas|last3=Mishkin|first3=Frederic S.|last4=Posen|first4=Adam S.|title=Inflation targeting: lessons from the international experience|date=2001|publisher=Princeton Univ. Press|isbn=9780691086897|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=MryLRLgkjGQC}}{{cite web|author1=John C. Williams , President and CEO , Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco|title=Inflation Targeting and the Global Financial Crisis: Successes and Challenges|url=http://www.frbsf.org/our-district/press/presidents-speeches/williams-speeches/2014/october/inflation-targeting-global-financial-crisis/|publisher=Federal Reserve Board of San Francisco|access-date=1 December 2016|date=31 October 2014}} A 2021 study in the American Political Science Review found that independent central banks with rigid inflation targeting policies produce worse outcomes in banking crises than independent central banks whose policy mandate does not rigidly prioritize inflation.{{Cite journal|last=Hansen|first=Daniel|date=2021|title=The Economic Consequences of Banking Crises: The Role of Central Banks and Optimal Independence|journal=American Political Science Review|volume=116 |issue=2 |language=en|doi=10.1017/S0003055421001325| pages=453–469 |s2cid=244148411 |issn=0003-0554|doi-access=free}}
=Benefits=
Inflation targeting allows monetary policy to "focus on domestic considerations and to respond to shocks to the domestic economy", which is not possible under a fixed exchange-rate system. Also, as a result of better inflation control and stability of economic growth, investors may more easily factor in likely interest rate changes into their investment decisions. Inflation expectations that are better anchored "allow monetary authorities to cut policy interest rates countercyclically".{{cite journal|author1=Maurice Obstfeld|title=Never Say Never: Commentary on a Policymaker's Reflections|journal=IMF Economic Review|date=2014|volume=62|issue=4|pages=656–693|author1-link=Maurice Obstfeld|doi=10.1057/imfer.2014.12|s2cid=154975315|url=http://eml.berkeley.edu/%7Eobstfeld/Fischer_final.pdf}}
Transparency is another key benefit of inflation targeting. Central banks in developed countries that have successfully implemented inflation targeting tend to "maintain regular channels of communication with the public". For example, the Bank of England pioneered the "Inflation Report" in 1993, which outlines the bank's "views about the past and future performance of inflation and monetary policy".{{cite web|title=Inflation Report|url=http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/Pages/inflationreport/default.aspx|publisher=Bank of England|access-date=20 January 2016|archive-date=7 July 2016|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20160707165834/http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/Pages/inflationreport/default.aspx|url-status=dead}} Although it was not an inflation-targeting country until January 2012, up until then, the United States' "Statement on Longer-Run Goals and Monetary Policy Strategy" enumerated the benefits of clear communication—it "facilitates well-informed decisionmaking by households and businesses, reduces economic and financial uncertainty, increases the effectiveness of monetary policy, and enhances transparency and accountability, which are essential in a democratic society".{{cite book |author1=Janet L. Yellen|title=Monetary Policy Report |date = 24 February 2015 |publisher=Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System |location=Washington, D.C. |url= http://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/files/20150224_mprfullreport.pdf|author1-link=Janet L. Yellen }}
An explicit numerical inflation target increases a central bank's accountability, and thus it is less likely that the central bank falls prey to the time-inconsistency trap. This accountability is especially significant because even countries with weak institutions can build public support for an independent central bank. Institutional commitment can also insulate the bank from political pressure to undertake an overly expansionary monetary policy.
An econometric analysis found that although inflation targeting results in higher economic growth, it does not necessarily guarantee stability based on their study of 36 emerging economies from 1979 to 2009.{{cite journal |last1=Amira |first1=Beldi |last2=Mouldi |first2=Djelassi |last3=Feridun |first3=Mete |year=2012 |title=Growth effects of inflation targeting revisited: empirical evidence from emerging markets |journal=Applied Economics Letters |volume=20 |issue=6 |pages=587–591 |doi=10.1080/13504851.2012.718054 |s2cid=154966050 }}
=Shortcomings=
Supporters of a nominal income target criticize the propensity of inflation targeting to neglect output shocks by focusing solely on the price level. Adherents of market monetarism, led by Scott Sumner, argue that in the United States, the Federal Reserve's mandate is to stabilize both output and the price level, and that consequently a nominal income target would better suit the Fed's mandate.{{cite journal |last1=Benchimol |first1=Jonathan |last2=Fourçans |first2=André |year=2019 |title=Central bank losses and monetary policy rules: a DSGE investigation |journal=International Review of Economics & Finance |volume=61 |issue=1 |pages=289–303 |doi=10.1016/j.iref.2019.01.010|s2cid=159290669 |url=https://hal.science/hal-02876656 }} Australian economist John Quiggin, who also endorses nominal income targeting, stated that it "would maintain or enhance the transparency associated with a system based on stated targets, while restoring the balance missing from a monetary policy based solely on the goal of price stability".{{cite web | url = http://johnquiggin.com/2012/01/27/inflation-target-tyranny/ | title = Inflation target tyranny | access-date = 28 January 2012 | last = Quiggin | first = John| date = 26 January 2012 }} Quiggin blamed the late-2000s recession on inflation targeting in an economic environment in which low inflation is a "drag on growth". In practice, many central banks conduct "flexible inflation targeting" where the central bank strives to keep inflation near the target except when such an effort would imply too much output volatility.{{cite news | first = Lars | last = Svensson | title = Flexible inflation targeting – lessons from the financial crisis | date = 21 September 2009 | url= http://www.bis.org/review/r090923d.pdf | work = speech at the workshop "Towards a new framework for monetary policy? Lessons from the crisis", organized by the Netherlands Bank, Amsterdam }}{{cite news|title=BoJ to pursue inflation target 'flexibly'|url=http://www.ft.com/cms/s/0/ddd94d14-a27e-11e2-bd45-00144feabdc0.html#axzz3xofkKmXj|access-date=20 January 2016|work=Financial Times|date=11 April 2013}}
Quiggin also criticized former Fed Chair Alan Greenspan and former European Central Bank President Jean-Claude Trichet for "ignor[ing] or even applaud[ing] the unsustainable bubbles in speculative real estate that produced the crisis, and to react[ing] too slowly as the evidence emerged".
In a 2012 op-ed, University of Nottingham economist Mohammed Farhaan Iqbal suggested that inflation targeting "evidently passed away in September 2008", referencing the 2008 financial crisis. Frankel suggested "that central banks that had been relying on [inflation targeting] had not paid enough attention to asset-price bubbles", and also criticized inflation targeting for "inappropriate responses to supply shocks and terms-of-trade shocks". In turn, Iqbal suggested that nominal income targeting or product-price targeting would succeed inflation targeting as the dominant monetary policy regime.{{cite news | first = Jeffrey | last = Frankel | title = The Death of Inflation Targeting | date = 16 May 2012 | url = http://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/the-death-of-inflation-targeting | work = Project Syndicate }} The debate continues and many observers expect that inflation targeting will continue to be the dominant monetary policy regime, perhaps after certain modifications.Lucrezia Reichlin and Richard Baldwin, eds. (2013), [http://www.voxeu.org/sites/default/files/file/P248%20inflation%20targeting(2).pdf "Is Inflation Targeting Dead? Central Banking After the Crisis"], Centre for Economic Policy Research (CEPR)
Empirically, it is not so obvious that inflation targeteers have better inflation control. Some economists argue that better institutions increase a country's chances of successfully targeting inflation.{{cite journal|author1=Haizhou Huang|author2=Shang-Jin Wei|title=Monetary Policies for Developing Countries: The Role of Institutional Quality|journal=Journal of International Economics|date=September 2006|volume=70|pages=239–52|doi=10.1016/j.jinteco.2005.09.001 |s2cid=33698841}} John Williams, a high-ranking Federal Reserve official, concluded that "when gauged by the behavior of inflation since the crisis, inflation targeting delivered on its promise".John C. Williams, (2014), [http://www.frbsf.org/our-district/press/presidents-speeches/williams-speeches/2014/october/inflation-targeting-global-financial-crisis/ "Inflation Targeting and the Global Financial Crisis: Successes and Challenges"], Essay presentation to the South African Reserve Bank Conference on Fourteen Years of Inflation Targeting in South Africa and the Challenge of a Changing Mandate, Pretoria, South Africa
In an article written since the COVID-19 pandemic, critics have pointed out that the Bank of Canada’s inflation-targeting has had unintended consequences, with persistently low interest rates over the last 12 years fuelling an increase in home prices by encouraging borrowing; and contributing to wealth inequalities by supporting higher equity values.{{Cite web |title=GESSAROLI: Artificially low interest rates -- we're paying the price |url=https://torontosun.com/opinion/columnists/gessaroli-artificially-low-interest-rates-were-paying-the-price |access-date=2022-04-14 |website=torontosun |language=en-CA}}
Inflation target
=Positive=
The typical numerical target of 2% has come under debate since the period of rapid inflation experienced following the monetary expansion during the COVID-19 pandemic. Mohamed El-Erian has suggested the Federal Reserve raise its inflation target to a (stable) 3% rate of inflation, saying "There's nothing scientific about 2%".{{Cite web |last=Ryssdal |first=Kai |date=2023-08-03 |title=El-Erian advises Federal Reserve to rethink its 2% inflation target |url=https://www.marketplace.org/2023/08/03/mohamed-el-erian-on-feds-inflation-target-theres-nothing-scientific-about-2/ |access-date=2023-08-08 |website=Marketplace |language=en-US}}
Over time, the compound effect of small annual price increases will significantly reduce a currency's purchasing power. For example, successfully hitting a target of +2% each year for 40 years would cause the price of a $100 basket of goods to rise to $220.80. Cumulative inflation can impact the perception of inflation.{{cite journal | last=McGranahan | first=Leslie | last2=Paulson | first2=Anna L. | title=The Incidence of Inflation: Inflation Experiences by Demographic Group: 1981-2004 | journal=FRB of Chicago Working Paper | date=2005 | url=https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3887185 | access-date=23 April 2025}}
A study found higher inflation is correlated with and causes lower real GDP per capita.{{cite web | last=Andrés | first=Javier | last2=Hernando | first2=Ignacio | title=Does Inflation Harm Economic Growth? Evidence from the OECD | website=NBER | date=1 January 1999 | url=https://www.nber.org/books-and-chapters/costs-and-benefits-price-stability/does-inflation-harm-economic-growth-evidence-oecd | access-date=23 April 2025}}
=Zero=
The drawbacks of positive and negative inflation targets can be minimized by choosing a target of zero inflation on average.{{cite journal | last=McCracken | first=Mike | last2=Lipsey | first2=Richard G. | last3=York | first3=Robert C. | title=Zero Inflation: The Goal of Price Stability | journal=Canadian Public Policy / Analyse de Politiques | volume=17 | issue=1 | date=1991 | doi=10.2307/3551206 | page=119 | url=https://www.jstor.org/stable/3551206?origin=crossref | access-date=23 April 2025| url-access=subscription }}
=Negative=
Some economists argue that inflation is more likely than deflation to cause an economic contraction.{{cite web|last1=Herbener|first1=Jeffrey|title=Written Testimony before the Subcommittee on Domestic Monetary Policy and Technology|url=http://financialservices.house.gov/uploadedfiles/hhrg-112-ba19-wstate-jherbener-20120508.pdf|website=U.S. House of Representatives Financial Services Committee|access-date=22 October 2016}}{{cite web|title=Should We Fear Deflation?|url=https://www.libertyclassroom.com/prices/|access-date=22 October 2016}} Andrew Atkeson and Patrick J. Kehoe argued that deflation is the necessary consequence of optimal monetary policy or zero interest-rate policy.{{cite journal |last1=Atkeson |first1=Andrew |first2=Patrick J. |last2=Kehoe |year=2004 |title=Deflation and Depression: Is There an Empirical Link? |journal=American Economic Review |volume=94 |issue=2 |pages=99–103 |doi=10.1257/0002828041301588 |url=http://minneapolisfed.org/research/sr/sr331.pdf }} The zero lower bound problem can be mitigated with helicopter money.{{cite report | last=Eggertsson | first=Gauti | last2=Woodford | first2=Michael | title=Optimal Monetary Policy in a Liquidity Trap | publisher=National Bureau of Economic Research | publication-place=Cambridge, MA | year=2003 | doi=10.3386/w9968 | doi-access=free | page=}}
=Variations=
In contrast to the usual inflation rate targeting, Laurence M. Ball proposed targeting long-run inflation using a monetary conditions index.{{Cite web |title="Policy Rules for Open Economies" |url=http://www.rba.gov.au/rdp/RDP9806.pdf |url-status=dead |archiveurl=https://web.archive.org/web/20090917130728/http://www.rba.gov.au/rdp/RDP9806.pdf |archivedate=17 September 2009}} In his proposal, the monetary conditions index is a weighted average of the interest rate and exchange rate. It will be easy to put many other things into this monetary conditions index.
In the "constrained discretion" framework, inflation targeting combines two contradicting monetary policies—a rule-based approach and a discretionary approach—as a precise numerical target is given for inflation in the medium term and a response to economic shocks in the short term. Some inflation targeters associate this with more economic stability.{{cite web |date=March 2014 |title=Inflation-Targeting, Flexible Exchange Rates and Macroeconomic Performance since the Great Recession |url=http://aei.pitt.edu/50256/1/WD394_Andersen_et_al_Inflation_Targeting.pdf |access-date=28 December 2014 |publisher=The Centre for European Policy Studies}}
Countries
There were 27 countries regarded by the Bank of England's Centre for Central Banking Studies as fully fledged inflation
targeters at the beginning of 2012.{{cite journal|publisher=Bank of England – Centre for Central Banking Studies|date=2012|title=State of the art of inflation targeting.|url=http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/education/Documents/ccbs/handbooks/pdf/ccbshb29.pdf|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20170811125823/http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/education/Documents/ccbs/handbooks/pdf/ccbshb29.pdf|url-status=dead|archive-date=2017-08-11|pages=17, 18–44}} Other lists count 26 or 28 countries as of 2010.{{cite web|last1=Jahan|first1=Sarwat|title=Inflation Targeting: Holding the Line|url=http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/basics/target.htm|publisher=IMF|access-date=18 January 2016|date=28 March 2012}}{{cite journal|last1=Roger|first1=Scott|title=Inflation Targeting Turns 20|journal=Finance & Development|date=March 2010|volume=47|issue=1|url=http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/2010/03/roger.htm|access-date=18 January 2016}} Since then, the United States and Japan have also adopted inflation targets although the Federal Reserve, like the European Central Bank, does not consider itself to be an inflation-targeting central bank.
In addition, South Korea (Bank of Korea) and Iceland (Central Bank of Iceland) and others.
See also
{{div col|colwidth=25em}}
- Cumulative process
- Fisher equation
- Inflationism
- Inflation accounting
- Inflation derivative
- Inflation hedge
- List of countries by inflation rate
- Monetarism
- Nominal income target
- Output gap
- Phillips curve
- Time value of money
- Taylor rule
- Welfare cost of inflation
{{div col end}}
References
{{Reflist}}
External links
- [http://www.centralbanknews.info/p/inflation-targets.html Table of Central Bank Inflation Targets]
{{portal|Economics}}
{{DEFAULTSORT:Inflation Targeting}}
{{Central banks}}