First-past-the-post voting
{{Short description|Plurality voting system}}
{{about|the single-winner system|multiple-winner systems|Plurality voting}}
{{Use dmy dates|date=March 2023}}
{{Electoral systems sidebar|expanded=Single-winner}}
First-past-the-post (FPTP)—also called choose-one, first-preference plurality (FPP), or simply plurality—is a single-winner voting rule. Voters mark one candidate as their favorite, or first-preference, and the candidate with more first-preference votes than any other candidate (a plurality) is elected, even if they do not have more than half of votes (a majority).
FPP has been used to elect part of the British House of Commons since the Middle Ages{{cite web |date=26 September 2016 |title=The Boundaries Review is a chance to bring back multi-member constituencies |url=https://blog.politics.ox.ac.uk/boundaries-review-chance-bring-back-multi-member-constituencies/}} before spreading throughout the British Empire. Throughout the 20th century, many countries that previously used FPP have abandoned it in favor of other electoral systems, including the former British colonies of Australia and New Zealand. FPP is still officially used in the majority of US states for most elections. However, the combination of partisan primaries and a two-party system in these jurisdictions means that most American elections behave effectively like two-round systems, in which the first round chooses two main contenders (of which one of them goes on to receive a majority of votes).{{Cite web |last1=Santucci |first1=Jack |last2=Shugart |first2=Matthew |last3=Latner |first3=Michael S. |date=2023-10-16 |title=Toward a Different Kind of Party Government |url=https://protectdemocracy.org/work/toward-a-different-kind-of-party-government/ |url-status=live |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20240716205506/https://protectdemocracy.org/work/toward-a-different-kind-of-party-government/ |archive-date=2024-07-16 |access-date=2024-07-16 |website=Protect Democracy |language=en-US |quote="Finally, we should not discount the role of primaries. When we look at the range of countries with first-past-the-post (FPTP) elections (given no primaries), none with an assembly larger than Jamaica’s (63) has a strict two-party system. These countries include the United Kingdom and Canada (where multiparty competition is in fact nationwide). Whether the U.S. should be called ‘FPTP’ itself is dubious, and not only because some states (e.g. Georgia) hold runoffs or use the alternative vote (e.g. Maine). Rather, the U.S. has an unusual two-round system in which the first round winnows the field. This usually is at the intraparty level, although sometimes it is without regard to party (e.g. in Alaska and California)."}}{{Cite book |last1=Gallagher |first1=Michael |title=The Politics of Electoral Systems |last2=Mitchell |first2=Paul |date=2005-09-15 |publisher=OUP Oxford |isbn=978-0-19-153151-4 |page=192 |language=en |chapter=The American Electoral System |quote="American elections become a two-round run-off system with a delay of several months between the rounds." |chapter-url=https://books.google.com/books?id=Igdj1P4vBwMC&q=%22American+elections+become+a+two-round+run-off+system+with+a+delay+of+several+months+between+the+rounds.%22&pg=PA3}}{{Citation |last1=Bowler |first1=Shaun |title=The United States: A Case of Duvergerian Equilibrium |date=2009 |work=Duverger's Law of Plurality Voting: The Logic of Party Competition in Canada, India, the United Kingdom and the United States |pages=135–146 |url=https://link.springer.com/chapter/10.1007/978-0-387-09720-6_9 |access-date=2024-08-31 |place=New York, NY |publisher=Springer |language=en |doi=10.1007/978-0-387-09720-6_9 |isbn=978-0-387-09720-6 |quote=In effect, the primary system means that the USA has a two-round runoff system of elections. |last2=Grofman |first2=Bernard |last3=Blais |first3=André|url-access=subscription }}
Example
{{Tenn voting example}}
In FPTP, only the first preferences matter. As such, the votes would be counted as 42% for Memphis, 26% for Nashville, 17% for Knoxville, and 15% for Chattanooga. Since Memphis has the most votes, it would win a FPTP election, even though it is far from the center of the state and a larger majority of voters would more strongly prefer Nashville than any other option. Conversely, instant-runoff voting would elect Knoxville, the easternmost city. This makes the election a center squeeze.
By contrast, both Condorcet methods and score voting would return Nashville (the capital of Tennessee).
Properties and effects
class="wikitable"
|+Table of pathological behaviors ! !Pathology !Explanation/details |
{{Xmark}}
|The frustrated majority paradox occurs when a majority of voters prefer some candidate Brighton to every other candidate, but Brighton still loses the election. First-past-the-post is vulnerable to this paradox because of vote-splitting.Felsenthal, Dan S. (2010) [http://eprints.lse.ac.uk/27685/1/Review_of_Paradoxes_Afflicting_Various_Voting_Procedures_(LSERO).pdf Review of paradoxes afflicting various voting procedures where one out of m candidates (m ≥ 2) must be elected] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210224094341/http://eprints.lse.ac.uk/27685/1/Review_of_Paradoxes_Afflicting_Various_Voting_Procedures_(LSERO).pdf |date=24 February 2021 }}. In: Assessing Alternative Voting Procedures, London School of Economics and Political Science, London, UK. |
{{Xmark}}
|The Condorcet loser paradox happens when a majority of voters prefer every other candidate to B, but Brighton still wins. First-past-the-post is vulnerable to this paradox because of vote-splitting. |
{{Xmark}}
|The center squeeze describes a type of violation of :Independence of irrelevant alternatives primarily affecting voting rules in the Plurality-rule family where the Condorcet winner is eliminated in an early round or otherwise due to a lack of first-preference support. |
{{Xmark}}
|A spoiler effect is when the results of an election between A and B is affected by voters' opinions on an unrelated candidate C. First-past-the-post does not meet this criterion, which makes it vulnerable to spoilers. |
{{Xmark}}
|The cloning paradox is a particular kind of spoiler effect that involves several perfect copies, or "clones", of a candidate. Candidate-cloning causes vote-splitting in FPP. |
{{Xmark}}
|The best-is-worst paradox occurs when an electoral system declares the same candidate to be in first and last place, depending on whether voters rank candidates from best-to-worst or worst-to-best. FPP demonstrates this pathology, because a candidate can be both the FPP winner and also the anti-plurality loser. |
{{Xmark}}
|Lesser-evil voting occurs when voters are forced to support a "lesser of two evils" by rating them higher than their actual favorite candidate. FPP is vulnerable to this pathology. |
{{Tick}}
| rowspan="2" |Since plurality does not consider later preferences on the ballot at all, it is impossible to either harm or help a favorite candidate by marking later preferences. Thus it passes both Later-No-Harm and Later-No-Help. |
{{Tick}} |
{{Tick}}
|The multiple-districts paradox refers to a particularly egregious kind of gerrymander, when it is possible to draw a map where a candidate who loses the election nevertheless manages to win in every electoral district. This is not possible under FPP, or other positional voting methods. |
{{Tick}}
|Perverse response occurs when a candidate loses as a result of receiving too much support from some voters, i.e. it is possible for a candidate to lose by receiving too many votes. FPP is not affected by this pathology. |
{{Tick}}
|The no-show paradox is a situation where a candidate loses as a result of having too many supporters. In other words, adding a voter who supports A over B can cause A to lose to B. FPP is not affected by this pathology. |
=Two-party rule=
{{Main|Duverger's law}}
File:First-past-the-post_2015.svg]]
Perhaps the most striking effect of FPP is the fact that the number of a party's seats in a legislature has little to do with its vote count in an election, only in how those votes were geographically distributed. Parties with few votes sometimes take more than few seats; often the most-popular party takes 20 percent more seats than its portion of the popular vote. Some criticize FPP for this, arguing that a fundamental requirement of an election system is to accurately represent the views of voters. FPP often creates "false majorities" by over-representing larger parties (giving a majority of the parliamentary/legislative seats to a party that did not receive a majority of the votes) while under-representing smaller ones.
In Canada, majority governments have been formed often but usually they are made up of a party that received less than a majority of votes in the election. A party forming a majority government and also winning a majority of the votes cast has happened only six times since 1900: 1900; 1904; 1917; 1940, 1958 and 1984.
In the United Kingdom, 19 of the 24 general elections since 1922 have produced a single-party majority government. In only two of them (1931 and 1935), the leading party took a majority of the votes across the UK.
In some cases, this can lead to a party receiving the plurality or even majority of the votes cast overall, yet still failing to gain a plurality of legislative seats. This results in a situation called a majority reversal or electoral inversion or wrong-winner result.{{Cite journal|journal=American Economic Journal: Applied Economics|pages=327–357|volume=14|url=https://www.nber.org/papers/w26247|title=Inversions in US Presidential Elections: 1836-2016|first1=Michael|last1=Geruso|first2=Dean|last2=Spears|first3=Ishaana|last3=Talesara|date=5 September 2019|issue=1|doi=10.3386/w26247|pmid=38213750 |pmc=10782436 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210319145533/https://www.nber.org/papers/w26247|access-date=14 July 2021|archive-date=19 March 2021|url-status=live}}{{Cite web |url=https://slide-finder.com/view/ELECTION-INVERSIONS-BY-VARIANTS.214192.html |title=Election Inversions By Variants of the U.S. Electoral College |access-date=14 July 2021 |archive-date=18 July 2021 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210718043847/https://slide-finder.com/view/ELECTION-INVERSIONS-BY-VARIANTS.214192.html |url-status=usurped |first=Nicholas R. |last=Miller |department=Department of Political Science |agency=UMBC }} Famous examples of the second-place party (in votes nationally) winning a majority of seats include the elections in Ghana in 2012, New Zealand in 1978 and 1981, and the United Kingdom in 1951.
Famous examples of the second most popular party (in votes nationally) winning a plurality of seats include the elections in Canada in 2019 and 2021 as well as in Japan in 2003. Even when a party wins more than half the votes in an almost purely two-party-competition, it is possible for the runner-up to win a majority of seats. This happened in Saint Vincent and the Grenadines in 1966, 1998, and 2020 and in Belize in 1993. Even with only two parties and equally-sized constituencies, winning a majority of seats just requires receiving more than half the vote in more than half the districts—even if the other party receives all the votes cast in the other districts—so just over a quarter of the vote is theoretically enough to win a majority in the legislature. With enough candidates splitting the vote in a district, the total number of votes needed to win can be made arbitrarily small.{{Citation needed|date=October 2024}}
= Two-party systems =
Under first-past-the-post, a small party may draw votes and seats away from a larger party that it is more similar to, and therefore give an advantage to one it is less similar to. For example, in the 2000 United States presidential election, the left-leaning Ralph Nader drew more votes from the left-leaning Al Gore, resulting in Nader spoiling the election for the Democrats. According to the political pressure group Make Votes Matter, FPTP creates a powerful electoral incentive for large parties to target similar segments of voters with similar policies. The effect of this reduces political diversity in a country because the larger parties are incentivized to coalesce around similar policies.{{Cite web|title=First Past the Post|url=https://www.makevotesmatter.org.uk/first-past-the-post|access-date=26 June 2020|website=Make Votes Matter|archive-date=31 July 2020|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200731164815/https://www.makevotesmatter.org.uk/first-past-the-post|url-status=live}} The ACE Electoral Knowledge Network describes India's use of FPTP as a "legacy of British colonialism".{{Cite web|title=India – First Past the Post on a Grand Scale|url=https://aceproject.org/main/english/es/esy_in.htm|access-date=25 June 2020|website=ACE Electoral Knowledge Network}}
Duverger's law is an idea in political science which says that constituencies that use first-past-the-post methods will lead to two-party systems, given enough time. Economist Jeffrey Sachs explains:
{{Blockquote|The main reason for America's majoritarian character is the electoral system for Congress. Members of Congress are elected in single-member districts according to the "first-past-the-post" (FPTP) principle, meaning that the candidate with the plurality of votes is the winner of the congressional seat. The losing party or parties win no representation at all. The first-past-the-post election tends to produce a small number of major parties, perhaps just two, a principle known in political science as Duverger's Law. Smaller parties are trampled in first-past-the-post elections.|from Sachs's The Price of Civilization, 2011{{Cite book |last=Sachs |first=Jeffrey |title=The Price of Civilization |date=2011 |publisher=Random House |isbn=978-1-4000-6841-8 |location=New York |page=107}}}}
However, most countries with first-past-the-post elections have multiparty legislatures (albeit with two parties larger than the others), the United States being the major exception.{{Cite journal |last1=Dunleavy |first1=Patrick |last2=Diwakar |first2=Rekha |year=2013 |title=Analysing multiparty competition in plurality rule elections |url=http://eprints.lse.ac.uk/38452/1/Dunleavy_Analysing%20multiparty_2014_author.pdf |journal=Party Politics |volume=19 |issue=6 |pages=855–886 |doi=10.1177/1354068811411026 |s2cid=18840573 |access-date=30 June 2016 |archive-date=9 June 2022 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20220609031929/http://eprints.lse.ac.uk/38452/1/Dunleavy_Analysing%20multiparty_2014_author.pdf |url-status=live }} There is a counter-argument to Duverger's Law, that while on the national level a plurality system may encourage two parties, in the individual constituencies supermajorities may cause the largest party to suffer fracturing.{{Cite journal |last1=Dickson |first1=Eric S.|author2-link=Kenneth Scheve |last2=Scheve |first2=Kenneth |year=2010 |title=Social Identity, Electoral Institutions and the Number of Candidates |journal=British Journal of Political Science |volume=40 |issue=2 |pages=349–375 |citeseerx=10.1.1.75.155 |doi=10.1017/s0007123409990354 |jstor=40649446|s2cid=7107526 }}
= Strongholds, key constituencies and kingmakers =
The distortions in geographical representation (artificial regionalism) provide incentives for parties to "write off regions" where they are weak and not have much chance of being elected. So they ignore the interests of areas in which they are too weak to stand much chance of gaining representation, leading to governments that do not govern in the national interest.
Further, during election campaigns the campaigning activity of parties tends to focus on marginal seats held by opponents where there is a prospect of a change in representation. These decisions leave safer areas (safe to one party or the other) excluded from participation in an active campaign.{{Cite web |date=2011-01-04 |title=First Past the Post is a 'broken voting system' |url=https://www.ippr.org/news-and-media/press-releases/first-past-the-post-is-a-broken-voting-system |access-date=15 November 2017 |website=ippr.org |publisher=Institute for Public Policy Research |archive-date=15 November 2017 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20171115223042/https://www.ippr.org/news-and-media/press-releases/first-past-the-post-is-a-broken-voting-system |url-status=live }} Political parties operate by targeting districts, directing their activists and policy proposals toward those areas considered to be marginal, either possible to be lost or won, where each additional vote is potentially more critical and has more value.{{Cite web |last=Terry |first=Chris |date=2013-08-28 |title=In Britain's first past the post electoral system, some votes are worth 22 times more than others |url=http://www.democraticaudit.com/2013/08/28/in-britains-first-past-the-post-electoral-system-some-votes-are-worth-22-times-more-than-others/ |access-date=15 November 2017 |website=democraticaudit.com |publisher=London School of Economics}}{{Cite web |last=Galvin |first=Ray |title=What is a marginal seat? |url=http://www.justsolutions.eu/marginals/startmarginals.html |access-date=15 November 2017 |website=justsolutions.eu |archive-date=15 November 2017 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20171115215649/http://www.justsolutions.eu/marginals/startmarginals.html |url-status=live }}
The ability of FPTP to manufacture majority governments has been cited by its supporters as an advantage over proportional representation systems. In the latter, smaller parties may act as 'kingmakers' in coalitions using their bargaining power and therefore, arguably, their influence on policy is more than proportional to their parliamentary size. This is largely avoided in FPP systems where majorities are generally achieved, even if the party holding power does not have majority of votes.{{cite journal |author=Brams/Kilgour. Dorey |title=Kingmakers and leaders in coalition formation |journal=Social Choice and Welfare |year=2013 |volume=41 |issue=1 |pages=1–18 |doi=10.1007/s00355-012-0680-4 |jstor=42001390 |s2cid=253849669 |url=https://www.jstor.org/stable/42001390 |hdl=10419/53209 |hdl-access=free |access-date=11 March 2023 |archive-date=11 March 2023 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20230311121637/https://www.jstor.org/stable/42001390 |url-status=live }} FPP often produces governments which have legislative voting majorities,{{Cite book |last=Andy Williams |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=6keDJpK0xL8C&pg=PA24 |title=UK Government & Politics |publisher=Heinemann |year=1998 |isbn=978-0-435-33158-0 |page=24 |access-date=11 October 2016 |archive-date=22 May 2024 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20240522102106/https://books.google.com/books?id=6keDJpK0xL8C&pg=PA24#v=onepage&q&f=false |url-status=live }} thus providing such governments the legislative power necessary to implement their electoral manifesto commitments during their term in office, if they choose to.
This may be beneficial in a country where the party's legislative agenda has broad public support, albeit potentially divided across party lines, or at least benefits society as a whole. However handing a legislative voting majority to a government that lacks popular support can be problematic where said government's policies favor only a fraction of the electorate, particularly if the electorate divides on tribal, religious, or urban–rural lines. There is also the perceived issue of unfair coalitions where a smaller party forms a coalition with other smaller parties and form a government, without a clear mandate as was the case in the 2009 Israeli legislative election where the leading party Kadima, was unable to form a coalition so Likud, a smaller party, formed a government without being the largest party.
The use of proportional representation (PR) may enable smaller parties to become decisive in the country's legislature and gain leverage they would not otherwise enjoy, although this can be somewhat mitigated by a large enough electoral threshold. FPP supporters argue that FPP generally reduces this possibility, except where parties have a strong regional basis. A journalist at Haaretz reported that Israel's highly proportional Knesset "affords great power to relatively small parties, forcing the government to give in to political blackmail and to reach compromises";{{Cite news |last=Ilan |first=Shahar |title=Major Reforms Are Unlikely, but Electoral Threshold Could Be Raised |newspaper=Haaretz |url=https://www.haaretz.com/1.5074292 |access-date=8 May 2010 |archive-date=21 August 2019 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190821221203/https://www.haaretz.com/1.5074292 |url-status=live }}{{Cite web |last=Macavei |first=Mihaela |publisher=University of Alba Iulia |location=Romania |title=Advantages and disadvantages of the uninominal voting system |url=http://www.uab.ro/reviste_recunoscute/reviste_drept/annales_10_2007/macavei_en.pdf |access-date=8 May 2010 |archive-date=24 December 2019 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20191224074113/http://www.uab.ro/reviste_recunoscute/reviste_drept/annales_10_2007/macavei_en.pdf |url-status=dead }} Tony Blair, defending FPP, argued that other systems give small parties the balance of power, and influence disproportionate to their votes.{{cite book|author=P. Dorey|title=The Labour Party and Constitutional Reform: A History of Constitutional Conservatism|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=JsaHDAAAQBAJ&pg=PA400|date=17 June 2008|publisher=Palgrave Macmillan UK|isbn=978-0-230-59415-9|pages=400–}}
The concept of kingmaker small parties is similar to Winston Churchill's criticism of the alternative vote system as "determined by the most worthless votes given for the most worthless candidates."{{cite book|author=Larry Johnston|title=Politics: An Introduction to the Modern Democratic State|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=ZcpZ1eADwSMC&pg=PA231|date=13 December 2011|publisher=University of Toronto Press|isbn=978-1-4426-0533-6|pages=231–}} meaning that votes for lesser-supported candidates may change the outcome of the election between the most-popular candidates. In this case however, it is an intended feature of the alternative vote, since those votes would have otherwise been wasted. In some sense the cross-party vote transfers make every vote count, as opposed to FPP, where as many as three-quarters or more of the votes may be wasted in a district. Anyway this effect is only possible when no candidate receives a majority of first preference votes. It is related to kingmaker premise in that the lesser-known candidates may encourage their supporters to rank the other candidates a certain way and thus have undue influence.
Supporters of electoral reform generally see the kingmaker ability as a positive development, and claim that cross party ties produced by some alternatives to FPP encourage less negative campaigning and encourage more positive campaigning, as candidates are pushed to appeal to a wider group of people. Opinions are split on whether the alternative vote (better known as instant runoff voting outside the UK) achieves this better than other systems.
= Extremist parties =
Supporters and opponents of FPP often argue whether FPP advantages or disadvantages extremist parties, and whether or not it pushes parties to less moderate positions.
FPP suffers from the center squeeze phenomenon, where more moderate candidates are squeezed out by more extreme ones. However, the different types (or the absence of) of party primaries may strengthen or weaken this effect. In general, FPP has no mechanism that would benefit more moderate candidates and many supporters of FPP defend it, even when it elects the largest and most unified (even if more polarizing) minority over a more consensual majority supported candidate. Allowing people into parliament who did not finish first in their district, as can occur in PR systems, was described by David Cameron as creating a "Parliament full of second-choices who no one really wanted but didn't really object to either.""David Cameron. "[http://www.telegraph.co.uk/news/politics/av-referendum/8485118/David-Cameron-why-keeping-first-past-the-post-is-vital-for-democracy.html David Cameron: why keeping first past the post is vital for democracy] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20180118220917/http://www.telegraph.co.uk/news/politics/av-referendum/8485118/David-Cameron-why-keeping-first-past-the-post-is-vital-for-democracy.html|date=18 January 2018}}." Daily Telegraph. 30 April 2011 But he overlooks how his premise only uses first choice votes, when affection for a voter's secondary preference might be almost on par with the affection held for their first choice, and also how under STV and IRV the final elected choices were all - or almost all - high up in popularity on the first count anyway.A Report on Alberta Elections 1905-1982
Because under FPP only the winner in each district gets representation, voters often engage in strategic voting, a form of self-censorship. This has prevented extreme left- and right-wing parties from gaining parliamentary seats{{Citation needed|date=September 2024}}. (Proportional representation generally does give these parties their due share of representation, so there is less push for strategic voting. Thus, strategic voting is applauded by some{{Who |date=March 2025}} as it keeps extremists from gaining seats.
But supporters of extremist parties do not always engage in strategic voting, and sometimes do achieve representation under FPP anyway. For one thing, winning a plurality in a district (perhaps 33 percent of votes in a district where likely no more votes are cast than equivalent to total votes/total seats) may take much fewer votes than it does to win a seat under PR, where the effective threshold is seldom much less than total votes/total seats. The need for strategic voting is mostly obviated under preferential voting systems, such as STV or IRV. Voters are allowed to rank other candidates, and if necessary their votes are transferred to where they will be used. Therefore they do not have to (or at least less often have to) strategically compromise on their first choice.
Additionally, due to the safe seats produced by FPP and the ability of the leading party to take majority of seats with less than majority of votes, extremists may use "burrowing from within" and conspiratorial nomination machinations to take over a professedly big-tent party. The Constitution Society published a report in April 2019 stating that, "[in certain circumstances] FPP can ... abet extreme politics, since should a radical faction gain control of one of the major political parties, FPP works to preserve that party's position. ...This is because the psychological effect of the plurality system disincentivises a major party's supporters from voting for a minor party in protest at its policies, since to do so would likely only help the major party's main rival. Rather than curtailing extreme voices, FPP today empowers the (relatively) extreme voices of the Labour and Conservative party memberships."{{Cite news|first=Peter|last=Walker|date=22 April 2019|title=First past the post abets extreme politics, says thinktank|work=The Guardian|url=https://www.theguardian.com/politics/2019/apr/23/first-past-the-post-abets-extreme-politics-says-thinktank|archive-url=https://ghostarchive.org/archive/20231206101252/https://www.theguardian.com/politics/2019/apr/23/first-past-the-post-abets-extreme-politics-says-thinktank|archive-date=6 December 2023|url-status=live|access-date=23 June 2020}}{{Cite web|title=The Electoral System and British Politics|url=https://consoc.org.uk/publications/the-electoral-system-and-british-politics/|website=consoc.org.uk|access-date=23 June 2020|archive-date=25 June 2020|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200625171041/https://consoc.org.uk/publications/the-electoral-system-and-british-politics/|url-status=live}} For example, the electoral system of Hungary, a mixed system dominated by FPP, saw the right-wing, populist party Fidesz win 135 seats in the 2022 Hungarian parliamentary election and has remain the largest party in Hungary since 2010 by changing the electoral system to mostly use FPP instead of the previous mixed system using mostly the two-round system. Since 2010, Fidesz has implemented other anti-democratic reforms, leading to the European Parliament no longer considering Hungary a full democracy.{{cite press release |title=MEPs: Hungary can no longer be considered a full democracy |date=15 September 2022 |publisher=European Parliament |url=https://www.europarl.europa.eu/news/en/press-room/20220909IPR40137/meps-hungary-can-no-longer-be-considered-a-full-democracy |ref=20220909IPR40137 |access-date=25 March 2023 |url-status=live |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20220915103936/https://www.europarl.europa.eu/news/en/press-room/20220909IPR40137/meps-hungary-can-no-longer-be-considered-a-full-democracy |archive-date=15 September 2022}} Additionally, electoral reform campaigners have argued that the use of FPP in South Africa was a contributory factor in the country adopting the apartheid system after the 1948 general election in that country.{{Cite web|last=Cowen|first=Doug|title=The Graveyard of First Past the Post|url=https://www.electoral-reform.org.uk/the-graveyard-of-first-past-the-post/|access-date=4 July 2020|website=Electoral Reform Society|archive-date=4 July 2020|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200704094624/https://www.electoral-reform.org.uk/the-graveyard-of-first-past-the-post/|url-status=live}}{{Cite web|last=Winter|first=Owen|date=25 August 2016|title=How a Broken Voting System Gave South Africa Apartheid in 1948|url=https://www.huffingtonpost.co.uk/owen-winter/south-africa-apartheid_b_11662272.html|access-date=4 July 2020|website=Huffington Post|archive-date=18 March 2021|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210318014711/https://www.huffingtonpost.co.uk/owen-winter/south-africa-apartheid_b_11662272.html|url-status=live}}
Leblang and Chan found that a country's electoral system is the most important predictor of a country's involvement in war, according to three different measures: (1) when a country was the first to enter a war; (2) when it joined a multinational coalition in an ongoing war; and (3) how long it stayed in a war after becoming a party to it.{{Cite journal|last1=Leblang |first1=D.|last2=Chan|first2=S.|date=2003|title=Explaining Wars Fought By Established Democracies: Do Institutional Constraints Matter?|journal=Political Research Quarterly|page=56-24: 385–400}}{{Cite web|title=PR and Conflict|url=https://www.makevotesmatter.org.uk/conflict|access-date=27 June 2020|website=Make Votes Matter|archive-date=31 July 2020|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200731155640/https://www.makevotesmatter.org.uk/conflict|url-status=live}} When the people are fairly represented in parliament, more of those groups who may object to any potential war have access to the political power necessary to prevent it. In a proportional democracy, war and other major decisions generally require the consent of the majority.{{Cite web|date=19 November 2017|title=What the Evidence Says|url=https://fairvotingbc.com/join-the-campaign-for-fair-voting/why-voting-reform/what-the-evidence-says/|access-date=27 June 2020|website=Fair Voting BC|archive-date=29 June 2020|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200629185607/https://fairvotingbc.com/join-the-campaign-for-fair-voting/why-voting-reform/what-the-evidence-says/|url-status=live}}{{Cite web|date=3 May 2010|title=Democracy: we've never had it so bad|url=https://www.theguardian.com/commentisfree/2010/may/03/democracy-first-past-the-post|access-date=27 June 2020|website=The Guardian|archive-date=22 May 2024|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20240522102019/https://www.theguardian.com/commentisfree/2010/may/03/democracy-first-past-the-post|url-status=live}} The British human rights campaigner Peter Tatchell, and others, have argued that Britain entered the Iraq War primarily because of the political effects of FPP and that proportional representation would have prevented Britain's involvement in the war.{{Cite web|last=Tatchell|first=Peter|date=3 May 2010|title=Democracy: we've never had it so bad|url=https://www.theguardian.com/commentisfree/2010/may/03/democracy-first-past-the-post|access-date=26 June 2020|website=The Guardian|archive-date=22 May 2024|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20240522102019/https://www.theguardian.com/commentisfree/2010/may/03/democracy-first-past-the-post|url-status=live}}{{Cite web|last=Barnett|first=Anthony|title=Will Labour's next leader finally break with first-past-the-post?|url=https://labourlist.org/2020/01/will-labours-next-leader-finally-break-with-first-past-the-post/|access-date=5 July 2020|website=Labourlist.org|date=10 January 2020|archive-date=5 July 2020|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200705132235/https://labourlist.org/2020/01/will-labours-next-leader-finally-break-with-first-past-the-post/|url-status=live}}{{Cite web|last=Root|first=Tim|date=30 September 2019|title=Making government accountable to the people|url=https://leftfootforward.org/2019/09/making-government-accountable-to-the-people/|access-date=5 July 2020|website=Left Foot Forward|archive-date=31 July 2020|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200731180947/https://leftfootforward.org/2019/09/making-government-accountable-to-the-people/|url-status=live}}
=Tactical voting=
{{Main|Strategic voting}}
To a greater extent than many others, the first-past-the-post method encourages "tactical voting". Voters have an incentive to vote for a candidate who they predict is more likely to win, as opposed to their preferred candidate who may be unlikely to win and for whom a vote could be considered as wasted. FPP wastes fewer votes when it is used in two-party contests. But waste of votes and minority governments are more likely when large groups of voters vote for three, four or more parties as in Canadian elections. Canada uses FPP and only two of the last seven federal Canadian elections (2011 and 2015) produced single-party majority governments. In none of them did the leading party receive a majority of the votes.
The position is sometimes summarized, in an extreme form, as "all votes for anyone other than the runner-up are votes for the winner."{{Cite web |last=Begany |first=Brent |date=2016-06-30 |title=The 2016 Election Proves The Need For Voting Reform |url=https://policyinterns.com/2016/06/30/the-2016-election-proves-the-need-for-voting-reform/ |access-date=2019-10-22 |website=Policy Interns |language=en |archive-date=22 October 2019 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20191022182755/https://policyinterns.com/2016/06/30/the-2016-election-proves-the-need-for-voting-reform/ |url-status=live }} This is because votes for these other candidates deny potential support from the second-placed candidate, who might otherwise have won. Following the extremely close 2000 U.S. presidential election, some supporters of Democratic candidate Al Gore believed one reason he lost to Republican George W. Bush is that a portion of the electorate (2.7%) voted for Ralph Nader of the Green Party, and exit polls indicated that more of them would have preferred Gore (45%) to Bush (27%).{{Cite news |last=Rosenbaum |first=David E. |date=24 February 2004 |title=THE 2004 CAMPAIGN: THE INDEPENDENT; Relax, Nader Advises Alarmed Democrats, but the 2000 Math Counsels Otherwise |work=The New York Times |url=https://query.nytimes.com/gst/fullpage.html?res=9B03E4D6173CF937A15751C0A9629C8B63 |access-date=7 February 2017 |archive-date=19 September 2008 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20080919015320/http://query.nytimes.com/gst/fullpage.html?res=9B03E4D6173CF937A15751C0A9629C8B63 |url-status=live }} The election was ultimately determined by the results from Florida, where Bush prevailed over Gore by a margin of only 537 votes (0.009%), which was far exceeded by the 97488 (1.635%) votes cast for Nader in that state.
In Puerto Rico, there has been a tendency for Independentista voters to support Populares candidates. This phenomenon is responsible for some Popular victories, even though the Estadistas have the most voters on the island, and is so widely recognised that Puerto Ricans sometimes call the Independentistas who vote for the Populares "melons", because that fruit is green on the outside but red on the inside (in reference to the party colors).
Because voters have to predict who the top two candidates will be, results can be significantly distorted:
- Some voters will vote based on their view of how others will vote as well, changing their originally intended vote;
- Substantial power is given to the media, because some voters will believe its assertions as to who the leading contenders are likely to be. Even voters who distrust the media will know that others do believe the media, and therefore those candidates who receive the most media attention will probably be the most popular;
- A new candidate with no track record, who might otherwise be supported by the majority of voters, may be considered unlikely to be one of the top two, and thus lose votes to tactical voting;
- The method may promote votes against as opposed to votes for. For example, in the UK (and only in the Great Britain region), entire campaigns have been organised with the aim of voting against the Conservative Party by voting Labour, Liberal Democrat in England and Wales, and since 2015 the SNP in Scotland, depending on which is seen as best placed to win in each locality. Such behavior is difficult to measure objectively.
Proponents of other voting methods in single-member districts argue that these would reduce the need for tactical voting and reduce the spoiler effect. Examples include preferential voting systems, such as instant runoff voting, as well as the two-round system of runoffs and less tested methods such as approval voting and Condorcet methods.
Wasted votes are seen as those cast for losing candidates, and for winning candidates in excess of the number required for victory. For example, in the UK general election of 2005, 52% of votes were cast for losing candidates and 18% were excess votes—a total of 70% "wasted" votes. On this basis a large majority of votes may play no part in determining the outcome. This winner-takes-all system may be one of the reasons why "voter participation tends to be lower in countries with FPP than elsewhere."{{Cite book|last=Drogus|first=Carol Ann|url=https://archive.org/details/introducingcompa00drog/page/257|title=Introducing comparative politics: concepts and cases in context|publisher=CQ Press|year=2008|isbn=978-0-87289-343-6|pages=[https://archive.org/details/introducingcompa00drog/page/257 257]|url-access=registration}}
=Geography=
The effect of a system based on plurality voting but in which the electorate are divided among many separate districts is that the larger parties, and parties with more geographically concentrated support, win a disproportionately large share of seats, while smaller parties and parties with more evenly distributed support win a disproportionately small share of seats. This is because the large parties win many seats and do not 'waste' many of their votes. As voting patterns are similar in about two-thirds of the districts, it is more likely that a single party will hold a majority of legislative seats under FPP than happens in a proportional system. This is especially true in multi-party situations where no party takes a majority of the vote. Despite the bias of FPP toward large parties, under FPP it is rare to elect a majority government that actually has the support of a majority of voters.
Because FPP produces many wasted votes and because the electorate are divided into the maximum number of separate districts, an election under FPP may be gerrymandered. When gerrymandering is used, electoral areas are designed deliberately to unfairly increase the number of seats won by one party by redrawing the map such that votes of the disadvantaged party are "packed" by creating one district in which it has an overwhelming majority of votes (whether due to policy, demographics which tend to favor one party, or other reasons), and many districts where it is at a disadvantage and will not win any seats, or the small party's votes are "cracked" where districts are drawn so that there is no district where the small party has a plurality. "The ReDistricting Game". USC Annenberg's Media Center. https://web.archive.org/web/20161204145449/http://www.redistrictinggame.org/learnaboutmission2.php. accessed May 19, 2025
The British Electoral Reform Society (ERS) says that regional parties benefit from this system. "With a geographical base, parties that are small UK-wide can still do very well" if they have local dominance or at least receive a plurality of votes in districts.{{Cite web |title=First Past the Post |url=https://www.electoral-reform.org.uk/voting-systems/types-of-voting-system/first-past-the-post/ |access-date=2019-12-16 |website=electoral-reform.org.uk |language=en-US |archive-date=13 December 2019 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20191213064535/https://www.electoral-reform.org.uk/voting-systems/types-of-voting-system/first-past-the-post/ |url-status=live }}
On the other hand, minor parties that do not concentrate their vote usually end up getting a much smaller proportion of seats than votes, as they lose most of the seats they contest and 'waste' most of their votes.{{Cite web |title=First Past the Post |url=https://www.electoral-reform.org.uk/voting-systems/types-of-voting-system/first-past-the-post/ |access-date=2019-12-05 |website=electoral-reform.org.uk |language=en-US |archive-date=13 December 2019 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20191213064535/https://www.electoral-reform.org.uk/voting-systems/types-of-voting-system/first-past-the-post/ |url-status=live }}
The ERS also says that in FPP elections using many separate districts "small parties without a geographical base find it hard to win seats".
Make Votes Matter said that in the 2017 general election, "the Green Party, Liberal Democrats and UKIP (minor, non-regional parties) received 11% of votes between them, yet they shared just 2% of seats", and in the 2015 general election, "[t]he same three parties received almost a quarter of all the votes cast, yet these parties shared just 1.5% of seats."{{Cite web |title=Make Votes Matter—Everything wrong with First Past the Post—Proportional Representation |url=https://www.makevotesmatter.org.uk/first-past-the-post |access-date=2019-12-16 |website=Make Votes Matter |language=en-GB |archive-date=2 November 2019 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20191102013320/https://www.makevotesmatter.org.uk/first-past-the-post |url-status=live }}
According to Make Votes Matter, in the 2015 UK general election UKIP came in third in terms of number of votes (3.9 million/12.6%), but gained only one seat in Parliament, resulting in one seat per 3.9 million votes. The Conservatives on the other hand received one seat per 34,000 votes.
The winner-takes-all nature of FPP leads to distorted patterns of representation, since it exaggerates the correlation between party support and geography. It creates artificial regionalism.
For example, in the UK the Conservative Party represents most of the rural seats in England, and most of the south of England, while the Labour Party represents most of the English cities and most of the north of England.{{Cite journal |title=Divided by Values: Jeremy Corbyn, the Labour Party and England's 'North-South Divide' |last1=Beech |first1=Matt |date=2020-07-03 |last2=Hickson |first2=Kevin|journal=Revue Française de Civilisation Britannique |volume=XXV |issue=2 |doi=10.4000/rfcb.5456 |s2cid=198655613 |doi-access=free }} This pattern hides the large number of votes cast for candidates of the non-dominant party in each place. Parties can find themselves without elected politicians in large portions of the country, heightening feelings of regionalism. Party supporters (who may nevertheless be a significant minority) in those sections of the country are unrepresented.
In the 2019 Canadian federal election Conservatives won 98% of the seats in Alberta and Saskatchewan with only 68% of the vote cast in those provinces. The lack of non-Conservative representation gives the appearance of greater Conservative support than actually exists.{{Cite web |title=First Past the Post |url=http://www.conservativeelectoralreform.org/support-reform/first-past-the-post/ |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20171115214736/http://www.conservativeelectoralreform.org/support-reform/first-past-the-post/ |archive-date=15 November 2017 |access-date=15 November 2017 |website=conservativeelectoralreform.org |publisher=Conservative Action for Electoral Reform}} Similarly, in Canada's 2021 elections, the Conservative Party won 88% of the seats in Alberta with only 55% of the Alberta vote and won 100% of the seats in Saskatchewan with only 59% of the provincial vote.{{cite web |url=https://enr.elections.ca/Provinces.aspx |title=Elections Canada – Results by Province(s) |work=2021 Elections Canada – Provinces |publisher=Elections Canada |date=2020-09-21 |access-date=2021-11-04 |archive-date=9 December 2022 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20221209014337/https://enr.elections.ca/Provinces.aspx |url-status=live }}
First-past-the-post within geographical areas tends to deliver (particularly to larger parties) a significant number of safe seats, where a representative is sheltered from any but the most dramatic change in voting behavior. In the UK, the Electoral Reform Society estimates that more than half the seats can be considered as safe.{{Cite web|date=2010-04-07|title=General Election 2010: Safe and marginal seats|url=https://www.theguardian.com/news/datablog/2010/apr/07/election-safe-seats-electoral-reform|access-date=15 November 2017|website=The Guardian|archive-date=3 March 2016|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20160303235530/http://www.theguardian.com/news/datablog/2010/apr/07/election-safe-seats-electoral-reform|url-status=live}} It has been claimed that members involved in the 2009 expenses scandal were significantly more likely to hold a safe seat.{{Cite web|last=Wickham|first=Alex|title="Safe seats" almost guarantee corruption|url=http://www.thecommentator.com/article/3678/_safe_seats_almost_guarantee_corruption|access-date=15 November 2017|website=thecommentator.com|archive-date=15 April 2021|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210415082539/http://www.thecommentator.com/article/3678/_safe_seats_almost_guarantee_corruption|url-status=dead}}{{Cite web|title=FactCheck: expenses and safe seats|url=http://www.channel4.com/news/articles/uk/factcheck+expenses+and+safe+seats/3388597.html|access-date=15 November 2017|website=channel4.com|publisher=Channel 4|archive-date=8 May 2021|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210508102457/http://www.channel4.com/news/articles/uk/factcheck+expenses+and+safe+seats/3388597.html|url-status=live}}
FPP variants
In some election systems, multi-seat districts (plural districts in the U.S.) are used but FPP may not be used because multi-seat contests are not used to fill the seats. This may be done by the members serving in staggered terms, with one being up for election in different years. This system is used in city elections in Portland, Maine.
Another way to avoid multi-seat contests in a multi-seat district is the seat/post system, where each seat is filled using a separate ballot. This was used in Canadian provincial elections -- to elect MLAs in Winnipeg districts in 1914 and 1915, and to elect all members in Prince Edward Island from 1867 to 1996.Parliament Guide
History
The House of Commons of England originated in 1341, during the Middle Ages as an assembly that included church leaders as well as the knights of each shire and burgesses of each large city of the Kingdom, each of which elected two members of parliament (MPs) by block plurality voting. Starting in the 19th century, electoral reform advocates pushed to replace these multi-member constituencies with single-member districts or like the Diggers to at least begin to use equal-sized districts. Reforms were made through the years, but a complete change to equal-sized single-member districts did not occur until 1948. In the meantime, block voting, limited voting and STV were used in multi-member districts holding as many as four members.David Klemperer, "Electoral Systems", p. 11 https://consoc.org.uk/wp-content/uploads/2019/04/David-Klemperer-Electoral-Systems-and-Electoral-Reform-in-the-UK-in-Historical-Perspective.pdf accessed May 19, 2025
Elections to the Canadian House of Commons have mostly been conducted using FPP. But eleven ridings at various times elected two MPs using block voting.Canadian Parliament Guide
The United States broke away from British rule in 1783, and its constitution provides for an electoral college to elect its president. Despite original intentions to the contrary, by the mid-19th century this college had transformed into a de facto use of FPP for each state's presidential election, with each state (excepting Nebraska and Maine) electing a party block voting or general ticket (multi-member slate) by mere plurality state-wide. This was further morphed through the introduction of the party primary, which made American presidential elections into a sort of two-round system in practice.
=Criticism and replacement=
{{multiple image
| direction = vertical
| width = 250
| footer = People campaigning against first-past-the-post and in favour of proportional representation
| image1 = Guelph Rally on Electoral Reform - National Day of Action for Electoral Reform - 11 Feb 2017 - 04.jpg
| image2 = Make Votes Matter ! No to FPTP. Yes to PR. (51868539320).jpg
}}
Non-plurality voting systems have been devised since at least 1299, when Ramon Llull came up with both the Condorcet and Borda count methods, which were respectively reinvented in the 18th century by the Marquis de Condorcet and Jean-Charles de Borda. More serious investigation into electoral systems came in the late 18th century, when several thinkers independently proposed systems of proportional representation to elect legislatures. The single transferable vote in particular was invented in 1819 by Thomas Wright Hill, and a quota-based electoral system was first used in a public election in 1840 by his son Rowland for the Adelaide City Council in Australia.Hoag and Hallett (1926). Proportional Representation. pp. 167–171 STV saw its first national use in Denmark in 1855 and was used in Tasmania state elections starting in 1897, permanently starting in 1909. STV was reinvented several times in the 19th century.
The Proportional Representation Society was founded in England in 1884 and began campaigning. STV was used to elect the British House of Commons's university constituencies between 1918 and their abolition in 1950.{{Citation needed|date=September 2024}}
Many countries that use first-past-the-post voting have active campaigns to switch to proportional representation (e.g. UK{{Cite web |title=What We Stand For |url=https://www.electoral-reform.org.uk/who-we-are/what-we-stand-for/ |website=electoral-reform.org.uk |access-date=25 June 2020 |archive-date=26 June 2020 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200626022218/https://www.electoral-reform.org.uk/who-we-are/what-we-stand-for/ |url-status=live }} and Canada{{Cite web |title=Home |url=https://www.fairvote.ca/ |website=Fair Vote Canada |access-date=25 June 2020 |archive-date=1 July 2020 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200701200741/https://www.fairvote.ca/ |url-status=live }}). Most modern democracies use some form of proportional representation.{{cite web |title=Electoral Systems around the World |url=https://www.fairvote.org/research_electoralsystems_world |website=FairVote.org |access-date=18 July 2020 |archive-date=11 September 2021 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210911132640/https://www.fairvote.org/research_electoralsystems_world |url-status=dead }}{{Cite web |title=Labour Campaign for Electoral Reform – About LCER |url=https://www.labourcampaignforelectoralreform.org.uk/About-LCER |website=labourcampaignforelectoralreform.org.uk |access-date=25 June 2020 |archive-date=11 August 2021 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210811033648/https://www.labourcampaignforelectoralreform.org.uk/About-LCER |url-status=dead }}
= Naming =
The name first-past-the-post is a reference to a kind of gambling in horse races. In a first-past-the-post wager, bettors would choose the single horse they thought would be the first one to make it past the finishing post.{{Cite web |date=2018-07-31 |title=First-past-the-post: a rogue's practice? |url=https://onelections.net/2018/07/31/first-past-the-post-a-rogues-practice/ |access-date=2024-09-09 |website=On Elections |language=en}}{{cite web |date=13 January 2016 |title=First past the post |url=https://nzhistory.govt.nz/politics/fpp-to-mmp/first-past-the-post |url-status=live |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20220524111637/https://nzhistory.govt.nz/politics/fpp-to-mmp/first-past-the-post |archive-date=24 May 2022 |access-date=25 May 2022 |website=nzhistory.govt.nz |publisher=Ministry for Culture and Heritage |language=en}}{{cite web |date=6 September 2010 |title=First Past the Post and Alternative Vote explained |url=https://www.gov.uk/government/publications/first-past-the-post-and-alternative-vote-explained |url-status=live |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20240118113041/https://www.gov.uk/government/publications/first-past-the-post-and-alternative-vote-explained |archive-date=18 January 2024 |access-date=13 July 2024 |website=gov.uk}} In academic contexts, the rule is typically called first-preference plurality (FPP), which describes the rule's behavior more precisely, or simply plurality.
Countries using FPP
= Legislatures elected exclusively by single-member plurality =
The following is a list of countries currently following the first-past-the-post voting system for their national legislatures.{{Cite web |title=Countries using FPTP electoral system for national legislature |url=http://www.idea.int/esd/type.cfm?electoralSystem=FPTP |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20141006214357/http://www.idea.int/esd/type.cfm?electoralSystem=FPTP |archive-date=6 October 2014 |access-date=3 December 2018 |website=idea.int}}{{Cite web |title=Electoral Systems |url=http://aceproject.org/epic-en/CDTable?question=ES005 |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://archive.today/20140826220250/http://aceproject.org/epic-en/CDTable?question=ES005 |archive-date=26 August 2014 |access-date=3 November 2015 |publisher=ACE Electoral Knowledge Network}}
{{div col|colwidth=22em}}
- {{Flagicon|Antigua and Barbuda}} Antigua and Barbuda
- {{Flagicon|Azerbaijan}} Azerbaijan
- {{Flagicon|Bahamas}} Bahamas
- {{Flagicon|Bangladesh}} Bangladesh
- {{Flagicon|Barbados}} Barbados
- {{Flagicon|Belarus}} Belarus
- {{Flagicon|Belize}} Belize
- {{Flagicon|Botswana}} Botswana
- {{Flagicon|Dominica}} Dominica
- {{Flagicon|Eritrea}} Eritrea
- {{Flagicon|Eswatini}} Eswatini
- {{Flagicon|Ethiopia}} Ethiopia
- {{Flagicon|The Gambia}} The Gambia
- {{Flagicon|Ghana}} Ghana
- {{Flagicon|Grenada}} Grenada
- {{Flagicon|Jamaica}} Jamaica
- {{Flagicon|Kenya}} Kenya
- {{Flagicon|North Korea}} North Korea
- {{Flagicon|Liberia}} Liberia
- {{Flagicon|Malaysia}} Malaysia
- {{Flagicon|Malawi}} Malawi
- {{Flagicon|Maldives}} Maldives
- {{Flagicon|Mauritius}} Mauritius
- {{Flagicon|Federated States of Micronesia}} Federated States of Micronesia
- {{Flagicon|Myanmar}} Myanmar
- {{Flagicon|Nigeria}} Nigeria
- {{Flagicon|Qatar}} Qatar
- {{Flagicon|Saint Kitts and Nevis}} Saint Kitts and Nevis
- {{Flagicon|Saint Lucia}} Saint Lucia
- {{Flagicon|Saint Vincent and the Grenadines}} Saint Vincent and the Grenadines
- {{Flagicon|Samoa}} Samoa
- {{Flagicon|Solomon Islands}} Solomon Islands
- {{Flagicon|Transnistria}} Transnistria[https://www.intellinews.com/breakaway-transnistria-fully-under-sheriff-s-control-as-obnovlenie-party-sweeps-board-in-parliament-election-198054/ Breakaway Transnistria fully under Sheriff's control as Obnovlenie party sweeps board in parliament election], bne IntelliNews, 3 December 2020
- {{Flagicon|Trinidad and Tobago}} Trinidad and Tobago
- {{Flagicon|Turkmenistan}} Turkmenistan
- {{Flagicon|Uganda}} Uganda
- {{Flagicon|Yemen}} Yemen
- {{Flagicon|Zambia}} Zambia
{{div col end}}
== Upper house only ==
{{div col|colwidth=22em}}
- {{Flagicon|Bhutan}} Bhutan
- {{Flagicon|Dominican Republic}} Dominican Republic
- {{Flagicon|Poland}} Poland
{{div col end}}
== Lower house only ==
{{div col|colwidth=22em}}
- {{Flagicon|Canada}} Canada (upper house not elected at all)
- {{Flagicon|India}} India
- {{Flagicon|Palau}} Palau
- {{Flagicon|United Kingdom}} United Kingdom
{{div col end}}
== Varies by state ==
{{div col|colwidth=22em}}
- {{Flagicon|United States}} United States (both houses){{efn|Prior to the 2020 election, the US states of Alaska and Maine completely abandoned FPTP in favor of Instant-runoff voting or IRV. In the US, 48 of the 50 states and the District of Columbia use FPTP-GT to choose the electors of the Electoral College (which in turn elects the president); Maine and Nebraska use a variation where the electoral vote of each congressional district is awarded by FPTP (or by IRV in Maine beginning in 2020), and the statewide winner (using the same method used in each congressional district in the state) is awarded an additional two electoral votes. In states that employ FPTP-GT, the presidential candidate gaining the greatest number of votes wins all the state's available electors (seats), regardless of the number or share of votes won (majority vs non-majority plurality), or the difference separating the leading candidate and the first runner-up.{{Cite web|title=Electoral College Frequently Asked Questions|url=https://www.archives.gov/federal-register/electoral-college/faq.html|access-date=23 October 2015 |date=6 July 2023 |archive-date=6 December 2023 |archive-url=https://archive.today/20231206102739/https://www.archives.gov/electoral-college/faq |url-status=live |work=National Archives}}}}
{{div col end}}
== Subnational legislatures ==
{{div col|colwidth=22em}}
- {{Flagicon|Cook Islands}} Cook Islands (New Zealand)
- {{Flagicon|US Virgin Islands}} US Virgin Islands
- {{Flagicon|Bermuda}} Bermuda
- {{Flagicon|Cayman Islands}} Cayman Islands
{{div col end}}
= Use of single-member plurality in mixed systems for electing legislatures =
The following countries use single-member plurality to elect part of their national legislature, in different types of mixed systems.
Mixed or hybrid system where FPP is used alongside block voting (fully majoritarian/plurality systems) or as part of mixed-member majoritarian systems (semi-proportional representation)
{{div col|colwidth=22em}}
- {{Flagicon|Brazil}} Brazil – in the Federal Senate, alongside plurality block voting (alternating elections)
- {{Flagicon|Hungary}} Hungary – as part of a mixed system (parallel voting with partial compensation)
- {{Flagicon|Ivory Coast}} Ivory Coast – in single-member electoral districts, alongside party block voting
- {{Flagicon|Iran}} Iran – in single-member electoral districts for Khobregan, alongside plurality block voting
- {{Flagicon|Japan}} Japan – as part of a mixed system (parallel voting)
- {{Flagicon|Marshall Islands}} Marshall Islands – FPP in single-member electoral districts, alongside MMDs of 2 to 5 seats using plurality block voting
- {{Flagicon|Mexico}} Mexico – as part of a mixed system (parallel voting)
- {{Flagicon|Nepal}} Nepal – as part of a mixed system (parallel voting){{Cite book |last=Bhuwan Chandra Upreti |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=TEq3D4evrO0C&pg=PA69 |title=Nepal: Transition to Democratic Republican State : 2008 Constituent Assembly |publisher=Gyan Publishing House |year=2010 |isbn=978-81-7835-774-4 |pages=69– |access-date=11 October 2016 |archive-date=22 May 2024 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20240522102013/https://books.google.com/books?id=TEq3D4evrO0C&pg=PA69#v=onepage&q&f=false |url-status=live }}
- {{Flagicon|Oman}} Oman – in single-member electoral districts, alongside plurality block voting
- {{Flagicon|Pakistan}} Pakistan – alongside seats distributed proportional to seats already won
- {{Flagicon|Philippines}} Philippines – as part of a mixed system (parallel voting){{efn|name=fn1}}
- {{Flagicon|Singapore}} Singapore – in single-member electoral districts, alongside party block voting
- {{Flagicon|South Korea}} South Korea – as part of a mixed system (parallel voting){{efn|As the usage of decoy lists by major parties is prevalent, the additional member system is de facto nullified.{{cite news |last=Nam |first=Hyun-woo |title=Major parties revert to criticized tactic to boost votes ahead of crucial election |url=https://www.koreatimes.co.kr/www/nation/2024/04/113_368264.html |work=The Korea Times |location= |publisher= |date=2024-02-05 |access-date=}}}}{{efn|name=fn1|The Philippines, South Korea and Thailand use the first-past-the-post voting system primarily; 80% or above of their members of parliament are elected by FPTP.}}
- {{Flagicon|Taiwan}} Republic of China (Taiwan) – as part of a mixed system (parallel voting)
- {{Flagicon|Tanzania}} Tanzania – as part of a mixed system (parallel voting)
- {{Flagicon|Thailand}} Thailand – as part of a mixed system (parallel voting){{efn|name=fn1}}{{div col end}}
As part of mixed-member proportional (MMP) or additional member systems (AMS)
{{div col|colwidth=22em}}
- {{Flagicon|Bolivia}} Bolivia
- {{Flagicon|Lesotho}} Lesotho
- {{Flagicon|New Zealand}} New Zealand
Subnational legislatures
- {{Flagicon|Scotland}} Scotland (United Kingdom){{div col end}}
= Heads of state elected by FPP =
{{div col|colwidth=22em}}
- {{Flagicon|Angola}} Angola (Double simultaneous vote for the presidential and legislative elections)
- {{Flagicon|Bosnia and Herzegovina}} Bosnia and Herzegovina (one for each main ethnic group)
- {{Flagicon|Cameroon}} Cameroon
- {{Flagicon|Democratic Republic of the Congo}} Democratic Republic of the Congo
- {{Flagicon|Equatorial Guinea}} Equatorial Guinea
- {{Flagicon|The Gambia}} The Gambia
- {{Flagicon|Guyana}} Guyana (Double simultaneous vote for the presidential and legislative elections)
- {{Flagicon|Honduras}} Honduras
- {{Flagicon|Iceland}} Iceland
- {{Flagicon|Kiribati}} Kiribati
- {{Flagicon|Malawi}} Malawi
- {{Flagicon|Mexico}} Mexico
- {{Flagicon|Nicaragua}} Nicaragua
- {{Flagicon|Nigeria}} Nigeria
- {{Flagicon|Palestine}} Palestine
- {{Flagicon|Panama}} Panama
- {{Flagicon|Paraguay}} Paraguay
- {{Flagicon|Philippines}} Philippines
- {{Flagicon|Rwanda}} Rwanda
- {{Flagicon|Singapore}} Singapore
- {{Flagicon|South Korea}} South Korea
- {{Flagicon|Taiwan}} Taiwan (from 1996 constitutional amendment)
- {{Flagicon|Tanzania}} Tanzania
- {{Flagicon|Venezuela}} Venezuela
{{div col end}}
=Former use=
{{incomplete list|date=July 2016}}
- Argentina (The Chamber of Deputies uses party list PR. Only twice used FPTP, first between 1902 and 1905 used only in the {{ill|1904 Argentine legislative election|lt=elections of 1904|es|Elecciones legislativas de Argentina de 1904}},{{Cite book |last=Milia |first=Juan Guillermo |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=NStcCgAAQBAJ&pg=PA40 |title=El Voto. Expresión del poder ciudadano |date=2015 |publisher=Editorial Dunken |isbn=978-987-02-8472-7 |location=Buenos Aires |pages=40–41 }}{{Dead link|date=May 2024 |bot=InternetArchiveBot |fix-attempted=yes }} and the second time between 1951 and 1957 used only in the elections of 1951 and 1954.){{Cite web |title=Law 14,032 |url=http://www.saij.gob.ar/legislacion/ley-nacional-14032.htm?bsrc=ci |website=Sistema Argentino de Información Jurídica |access-date=19 October 2017 |archive-date=20 October 2017 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20171020135532/http://www.saij.gob.ar/legislacion/ley-nacional-14032.htm?bsrc=ci |url-status=live }}
- Australia (replaced by IRV in 1918 for both the House of Representatives and the Senate, with STV being introduced to the Senate in 1948)
- Belgium (adopted in 1831, replaced by party list PR in 1899)—{{cite encyclopedia | title=Kiesstelsel. §1.1 Federale verkiezingen | encyclopedia=Encarta-encyclopedie Winkler Prins | publisher=Microsoft Corporation/Het Spectrum | year=1993–2002}} the Member of the European Parliament for the German-speaking electoral college is still elected by FPTP{{cite web | url=https://www.vrt.be/vrtnws/en/2019/03/20/elections-2019-the-european-parliament/ | title=Elections 2019: The European Parliament | work=Flanders News | date=17 April 2019 | access-date=2 December 2022 | quote=The European Parliament elections in Belgium will be held on 26 May, the same day as the regional and federal elections. In the European elections there are three Belgian constituencies: the Dutch-speaking electoral college, the Francophone electoral college and the German-speaking electoral college. | archive-date=6 April 2023 | archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20230406012005/https://www.vrt.be/vrtnws/en/2019/03/20/elections-2019-the-european-parliament/ | url-status=live }}
- Cyprus (replaced by proportional representation in 1981)
- Denmark (replaced by proportional representation in 1920)
- Hong Kong (adopted in 1995, replaced by party list PR in 1998)
- Italy (used between 1860 and 1882, and between 1892 and 1919)
- Lebanon (replaced by proportional representation in June 2017)
- Lesotho (replaced by MMP Party list in 2002)
- Malta (replaced by STV in 1921)
- New Zealand (replaced by MMP in 1996)
- Papua New Guinea (replaced by IRV in 2002){{Cite web |date=12 December 2003 |title=PNG voting system praised by new MP |url=http://www.abc.net.au/ra/newstories/RANewsStories_1015553.htm |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20050104074304/http://www.abc.net.au/ra/newstories/RANewsStories_1015553.htm |archive-date=4 January 2005 |access-date=19 May 2015 |publisher=Australian Broadcasting Corporation}}
- Portugal (replaced by party list PR){{Cite web|title=Which European countries use proportional representation?|url=https://www.electoral-reform.org.uk/which-european-countries-use-proportional-representation/|access-date=2019-12-01|website=electoral-reform.org.uk|language=en-US|archive-date=27 December 2019|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20191227222723/https://www.electoral-reform.org.uk/which-european-countries-use-proportional-representation/|url-status=live}}
- Serbia (adopted in 1990, replaced by party list PR in 1992){{Cite web |last1=MrdaljPolitikolog |first1=Mladen |last2=Univerzitetu |first2=Predavač na Webster |date=2020-10-08 |title=Sedam zabluda o uvođenju većinskog izbornog sistema |url=https://talas.rs/2020/10/08/sedam-zabluda-o-uvodenju-vecinskog-izbornog-sistema/ |access-date=2024-01-13 |website=Talas.rs |language=en-US |archive-date=13 January 2024 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20240113164807/https://talas.rs/2020/10/08/sedam-zabluda-o-uvodenju-vecinskog-izbornog-sistema/ |url-status=live }}
- South Africa (replaced by party list PR in 1994)
See also
Notes
{{notelist}}
References
{{reflist}}
External links
{{commons category}}
- [https://www.idea.int/publications/catalogue/electoral-system-design-new-international-idea-handbook A handbook of Electoral System Design] from [http://www.idea.int International IDEA]
- [https://aceproject.org/epic-en/es#ES05 ACE Project: What is the electoral system for Chamber{{nbsp}}1 of the national legislature?]
- [http://www.aceproject.org/main/english/es/esd01.htm ACE Project: First Past The Post]—detailed explanation of first-past-the-post voting
- [http://www.aceproject.org/ace-en/topics/es/ese/ese01/ese01a/ ACE Project: Electing a President using FPTP]
- {{usurped|1=[http://webarchive.loc.gov/all/20090521142509/http://aceproject.org//ace%2Den//topics//es//esy//esy_in ACE Project: FPTP on a grand scale in India]}}
- [http://citizensassembly.arts.ubc.ca/ The Citizens' Assembly on Electoral Reform says the new proportional electoral system it proposes for British Columbia will improve the practice of democracy in the province.]
- [https://nobcprorep.ca Vote No to Proportional Representation BC]
- [http://citizensassembly.arts.ubc.ca/public/extra/factsheet_intro.xml.htm Fact Sheets on Electoral Systems provided to members of the Citizens' Assembly on Electoral Reform, British Columbia.]
- [http://www.game-point.net/misc/election2005/ The Problem With First-Past-The-Post Electing (data from UK general election 2005)]
- {{YouTube|s7tWHJfhiyo|The Problems with First Past the Post Voting Explained (video)}}
- [http://www.prsa.org.au/pluralit.htm The fatal flaws of First-past-the-post electoral systems]
{{Voting systems}}
{{2011 United Kingdom Alternative Vote referendum}}
{{Parliament of NZ}}
{{DEFAULTSORT:First-Past-The-Post}}